Friday, February 10, 2017

Balance of trade: Robert Kuttner on Dani Rodrik

Balance of Trade

By Robert Kuttner

Illustrations by John Weber

THERE ARE ECONOMISTS who teach the well-known postulate that free trade improves global well-being. There are other social scientists and popular critics who contend that laissez-faire trade can be bad for equality, for social stability, and even for economic efficiency, just as pure laissez-faire is not optimal at home.

And then there is Dani Rodrik.

Rodrik, the Ford Foundation Professor of International Political Economy at the Kennedy School, is close to a unique specimen in the field of economics. He is a respectful critic of some of the most cherished suppositions of his profession, notably in his books and articles expressing qualms about globalization. But Rodrik does it as a superb technical economist, with humility, precision, wit, intellectual curiosity, and an astonishing range of reading across disciplines.

A few other social scientists have pursued a broad interdisciplinary approach. One of Rodrik's heroes, the economist and philosopher Albert Hirschman was fond of calling himself a disciplinary "trespasser." Rodrik, however, also publishes extensive quantitative work in the most prestigious refereed economics journals. All this makes him unusual, and makes his gentle heresies well grounded in both theory and evidence, and impossible to dismiss out of hand.

Rodrik came to wide attention in 1997, when he was still in his 30s, with a short book titled Has Globalization Gone Too Far? The tentative title, suggesting cautious inquiry, was classic Rodrik. At the time, the all but universal view among economists was the more globalization, the better. One of the core precepts in economics is the idea of comparative advantage, dating back to David Ricardo in 1817: Open trade allows each country to do what it does best, increasing general efficiency.

Rodrik basically agreed, but he felt that what he later called "deep globalization" could be too much of a good thing. The intensification of globalization, he wrote, created several problems that economists looking only at textbook efficiency tended to miss. "The most serious challenge for the world economy," he wrote, is to ensure "that international economic integration does not contribute to domestic social disintegration." (This was nearly two decades before the rise of the Tea Party and the anti-trade backlash.) On the basis of careful empirical work, Rodrik concluded that "globalization makes it difficult to sustain the postwar social bargain" of labor peace in exchange for "steadily improving worker pay and benefits." That was a hard argument for many of his economist colleagues to swallow. In a free market, worker pay would (and should) reflect worker productivity—end of story.

But Rodrik pointed to two risks from excessive globalization—the conventional, oft-cited risk that the dislocations of globalization would lead to support for protectionism; and a second more serious risk—that globalization would tear societies apart, undermining democracy and widening inequality and social conflict. Rodrik complemented his economic analysis with a political one. He quoted political scientists who had observed that nations with open economies and extensive trade tended to have larger welfare states as social buffers against the dislocations of trade. "But once globalization moves beyond a certain point," Rodrik wrote, "the government can no longer finance the necessary transfers because the tax base becomes too footloose."

As notable as the book itself was who published it. The slim volume was commissioned by the Institute for International Economics, the citadel of the orthodox view of trade. C. Fred Bergsten the institute's longtime director, observed some emerging cracks in the consensus view, and wanted his institute to be part of the debate; he also wanted a well-qualified economist to present the critique. Some of Bergsten's colleagues and board members were appalled, but the book enriched the conversation and put Rodrik on a broader intellectual map.

Fourteen years later, in 2011, Rodrik published a grand synthesis of his view of trade, The Globalization Paradox, which many regard as his masterwork. The basic point: Markets and states are not adversaries—they need each other. The paradox of the title is that markets require states, but too much globalization undermines states, the repositories of political democracy, upholders of the law on which markets rest, and brokers of social contracts. He proposed what he called a "trilemma": It is not possible to have deep globalization, political democracy, and a competent nation-state. At best, we can have two out of three.

Rodrik's remedy is to return to something like the more moderate globalization of the Bretton Woods era, and to allow nation-states more sovereignty to determine their own preferred course. "Countries have the right to protect their own social arrangements, regulations, and institutions," Rodrik wrote. "That's more important than squeezing out the last bit of purported efficiency gains from trade," he argues.

Over two decades, Rodrik has had the professional satisfaction of being at the cutting edge of a dissenting view of trade that has now become entirely mainstream. "It's very clear that the profession has moved in his direction," says the Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz, who was one of Rodrik's teachers at Princeton. "The institutional view at the IMF is now that capital controls are sensible, and industrial policy is now defended by the World Bank. Overall, he's been proven right." Indeed, the IMF's Prakash Lounging recently wrote, referring to Rodrik's 1997 work, "His skepticism about the benefits of unfettered flows of capital across national boundaries is now conventional wisdom."

For a time, Rodrik occupied a lonely niche; now he has company. "Twenty years ago," he recalls, "economists would tell me, 'Do you really want to say this in public—It will just feed the barbarians. Your arguments will be abused by protectionists.' My answer was 'What makes you think there aren't barbarians on the other side—multinationals abusing patents and taxes, banks pushing for too much speculation?'"

 

DANI RODRIK WAS BORN in Istanbul to a Sephardic Jewish family. Centuries ago, the family name was most likely a variation on Rodrigues. He attended an English-language high school, the celebrated Robert College—the oldest American-sponsored school abroad—where by his own account he was a "good but not outstanding student." But he was good enough to be accepted by Harvard.

From Harvard College, where he majored in government, writing an undergraduate thesis comparing rural political mobilization in Egypt and Turkey, he went to the Woodrow Wilson School of Public & International Affairs at Princeton, expecting to get a degree in one of the other social sciences. But after getting an MPA, he decided to pursue a doctorate in economics. "My epiphany came at the library one day, when I held recent issues of the American Political Science Review (APSR) and American Economic Review (AER) side by side," he observes. "I realized I would be able to read many of the articles in the APSR if I did a PhD in economics; but the AER would be completely inaccessible to me if I did a PhD in political science."

His mentor and dissertation adviser was Avinash Dixit, one of the most respected and mainstream of trade economists, "a modeler's modeler," Rodrik recalls. Even though Rodrik later became known mainly for his applied work on economic development and on trade, his dissertation at Princeton was mostly theory, no data. "The only numbers in it were the page numbers," he says. Yet his work persuasively demonstrated that some standard assumptions did not hold water.

After Princeton, Rodrik chose a position in 1985 at the Kennedy School, a congenial place to cross boundaries, he later noted—boundaries between economic theory and economic policy, and between economics and other social sciences. Except for short stints at Columbia and Princeton's Institute for Advanced Study, he has been at the Kennedy School ever since.

A Rodrik signature is to follow where the data lead him, even when the result challenges his own preconceptions. Among economists, Rodrik is fairly indulgent of targeted government policy as a legitimate tool of development. Yet as a student of comparative institutions and a quantitative economist, he makes clear that what works in Taiwan doesn't necessarily work in Argentina.

Rodrik has played against type working with his Kennedy School colleague Robert Lawrence on South Africa's industrial policy, South Africa uses a system of tariffs to incentivize auto manufacturers to build factories there. Tariffs against imports are kept high; but for each car that an automaker builds in South Africa, it may import a second car tariff-free. That strategy has helped create a local auto industry and produced some manufacturing jobs, but Rodrik calculated that South African consumers pay the price in far more costly cars, and the gains go mainly to BMW and Mercedes.

"He crunched the numbers," says Lawrence, whose own views on trade are somewhat more orthodox than Rodrik's. "I was surprised and impressed. He held the policies to a higher economic standard."

Lawrence says he's learned from Rodrik that the utilitarian view that freer markets produce improved overall outcomes is not all that matters. Rodrik is fond of quoting the political philosopher Michael Walzer that some seemingly efficient forms of exchange are "blocked" in order to serve other values. We prohibit child labor at home, but by importing products made by children, we tolerate the practice via the back door of trade. "I never quite saw it," Lawrence says, "until I heard Dani explain the concept of blocked exchanges."

 

RODRIK'S CURRENT COURSES at the Kennedy School suggest both his intellectual range and his passion for technical economics. His course on economic development, co-taught with two colleagues, Asim Khwaja and Rohini Pande, compares theories of development with empirical studies and outcomes. The readings cut across economic history, theory, philosophy, quantitative analysis, and extensive case study. About 80 percent of the students are international. This is a core course for the Kennedy School's MPA/ID (International Development) program, for which Rodrik was the longtime faculty chair. "I often intend to pop in for a few minutes just to see how the class is going," says the program director, Carol Finney, "and I find myself staying because of the elegance of his lectures."

Rodrik's other class, a seminar titled "Ideas and Interests," looks at a range of policy problems, drawing on literature from economics, political science, sociology, and history. One of Rodrik's core beliefs is that ideas matter. "The ideas of a very few people, such as Keynes and Harry Dexter White, had immense influence on the architecture of postwar reconstruction," he says. "And ideas also mattered in the reversal that came in the Reagan-Thatcher period."

Rodrik's most recent book, Economics Rules (a characteristic Rodrik pun), is a careful sorting out of what economics does well and not so well. It is a combination love letter to his profession and lover's quarrel. "When models are used judiciously," he writes, "they are a source of illumination. When used dogmatically, they lead to hubris and errors in policy." Too many economists, he adds, "are in love with the math and forget its instrumental nature." Yet Rodrik passionately defends economics against economist-bashers. Math can be used to excess, but it also has the great virtue of being transparent. When two well-known Harvard economists published an influential paper that turned out to have an important technical mistake, which was discovered by a humble graduate student, Rodrik took this as cause for celebration—not because it showed the hubris of economists but because it demonstrated the openness of the discipline. "Ultimately, what determines the standing of a piece of research is not the affiliation, status, or network of the author, but how well it stacks up to the research criteria of the profession itself," he writes. "Because models enable the highlighting of error, anyone can do it."

The book, written with grace and wit, is a compendium of cases in which the insights of economic analysis produced useful policy innovations—and other cases in which economists overreached. Rather than being a universal set of rules, Rodrik insists, the premises of economics are context-dependent. Economics Rules closes with two sets of 10 commandments, one for economists and the other for would-be critics of the discipline. Commandment no. 9 for economists: "Efficiency is not everything." Commandment no. 8 for non-economists: "Economists don't (all) worship markets, but they know better how they work than you do."

One of the most often cited of Rodrik's papers, published in 2000 by the National Bureau of Economic Research, was a study he did with a graduate student, Francisco Rodriguez, in which the two decided to take a deep look at five of the most influential papers that claimed large growth gains from trade liberalization. Reverse engineering the methodology of the papers, they found that many of the assumptions were flawed and the gains were seriously overstated. Rodrik was challenged by some, not on the quality of his research but on his motivations. Yet it is technical work of this caliber, combined with a clear love of his profession, that gives him the credibility to be taken seriously as a critic.

 

IN HIS SPARE TIME, Rodrik also got involved in some Turkish derring-do. His father-in-law is a retired four-star general, Çetin Dogan, who belongs to the generation of military leaders who view themselves as guardians of a secular, constitutional Turkey in the spirit of modern Turkey's founder, Kemal Atatürk. (Rodrik's wife is Pinar Dogan, lecturer in public policy at HKS.) In 2003, documents were published in a leading Istanbul daily accusing General Dogan of masterminding a foiled coup against the Islamist government led by (now President) Recep Tayyip Erdogan. The general and more than 200 supposed-conspirators were vilified in the media and eventually tried and sentenced to long prison terms. Supporters of the exiled cleric Fethullah Gülen, at the time a regime ally, were especially active in promoting the case against Dogan.

Rodrik and his wife became leaders of the movement to exonerate General Dogan and hundreds of other defendants. They showed the incriminating documents to be forgeries, and eventually, in 2014, Turkey's constitutional court ordered Dogan and other officers freed. In the meantime, President Erdogan and Gülen had become sworn enemies, and this past July, Erdogan used a real attempted coup, allegedly organized by Gülen followers, to suspend civil liberties and purge dissenters. Dogan, long retired and vilified by Gülenists, was neither involved nor accused.

In the course of working to exonerate the general, Rodrik, whose first and last names are far from typically Turkish, encountered anti-Semitism and charges that he was working for Israel's Mossad. "On my visits to Turkey," he says, "people sometimes tell me how well I speak Turkish. I tell them that their Turkish is not so bad, either."

Though Rodrik writes elegant prose in books intended for general readers as well as scholars (all the more remarkable since English is not his first language), he is not quite a celebrity public intellectual. Unlike better-known figures in his profession with similar crossover appeal, such as Paul Krugman, Rodrik has opted to devote almost all his attention to the academy, continuing scholarly work along with the occasional book written for a broader audience. Although he has worked extensively with governments in developing countries, he has not gotten involved in government or politics in the United States. By temperament, he is not a self-promoter. You will find numerous Rodrik articles and papers, but only very intermittent Rodrik blog posts. Since he teaches mostly MPA/IDs, Rodrik's broader influence comes less in the form of a "Rodrik School" of economics than in the applied work of practitioners who look to him as a mentor.

Rodrik's most notable awards, appropriately, are named for economic thinkers who pushed against the conventions of the profession. He received the Albert Hirschman Prize from the Social Science Research Council, and the Wassily Leontief Award from the Tufts Global Development and Environment Institute. But it seems that recognition and respect for heterodox thinkers like Rodrik is now becoming mainstream.


--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV

The Winners and Losers Radio Show
7-9 AM Weekdays, The EPIC Radio Player Stream, 
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio:Hot new podcasts on EPIC Radio

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio
Post: Hot new podcasts on EPIC Radio
Link: http://www.enlightenradio.org/2017/02/hot-new-podcasts-on-epic-radio.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio:Sci-fi theater playlists Feb 10

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio
Post: Sci-fi theater playlists Feb 10
Link: http://www.enlightenradio.org/2017/02/sci-fi-theater-playlists-feb-10.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

Political economy of Iran

via Portside

Faramarz Dadvar
January 26, 2017
Portside
 
The danger of Donald Trump resorting to military action to prop up his failing policies cannot be over-looked. National Security Advisor Michael Flynn threatened retaliation against Iran, which for those of us of a certain age sounded like the Gulf of Tonkin incident (used as justification for War in Vietnam) - later proved to be a fabrication. What really is Iran with a population of 82 million people? Here is a report on what is actually happening in Iran today.
 
 

View of downtown Tehran from the Tochal Gondola, Photo credit: Deborah James // Global Exchange,
 
 

 

In Iran, since the 1st year after the 1979 people's revolution, theocratic repression has dominated the country. Although people's resistance to the Islamic Republic started right from the beginning, it never grew to a wide, mass-oriented uprising. The only major political upheaval, since the revolution, has been an upsurge of the democratic, "green" movement, in opposition to the 2009 presidential rigged election, and it, unfortunately, was crushed ruthlessly by the security forces. Otherwise, the social movements, particularly labor, women and human rights activists, continue with their daily struggles. Now, hundreds of pro-democracy activists remain in prison and, due to the absence of civil liberties and labor rights and the suppression of independent active opposition, there is no serious prospect for radical change in the political system for democracy and economic justice.
 
With the coming of the "moderate" Hasan Rouhani to the presidency in 2012, a nuclear agreement was made with the world major powers and it is supposed to remove economic sanctions and thus, as a result, contribute to more open economic relations with the outside world. Some improvements have already taken place and, based on the report by the World Bank, last year the rate of economical growth was 5.4 percent and production and export of oil had increased 3.1 percent (3.63 million barrels produced daily and 1.43 million barrels exported daily). But still, economic condition for the majority of people is unbearable. Inflation is near 10 percent and the official index for unemployment is 2.7 million and underemployment is over 5 million. Based on an International Monetary Fund (IMF) report, unemployment is above 11 percent (Tasnim: January 2nd, 2017). From a population of more than 80 million Iranians, around 15 million live below the poverty line. Living conditions for majority of the rest of the population is not far from poverty.
 
Iran, like many countries in the region, faces obstacles such as absence of the rule of law and transparency. The economy is under the control of an oligarchic group in which the supreme leader Ayatollah Ali Khamenei and the ruling elites have monopoly control of oil revenue and state budgets. As far as problems of corruption and nepotism are concerned, it is a fact that a small group of investors connected to the regime have better access to financial resources (many names including close relatives of the supreme leader and the president are exposed, publicly). In fact, the economy in Iran is primarily a rentier system, in which an unproductive economic system of activities based mainly on oil revenue, with wide class division, dominates the society. Much of the wealth is in the hands of a small ruling group, among them, top ruling clerics, governmental and military officials plus their private business partners.
 
The country also is entangled in a capitalist oriented economic crisis and confronts, among them, the impasse of secular economic stagnation (growth without the conventional job creation). This part of the problem is derived from the economic hurdle of primary-accumulation of capital without expanded production, but instead expansion in financialization of the economy. In today's  capitalist world, partly due to the dilemma of over-accumulation, capitalist investments are channeled towards "waste" such as in finance, service and war industries (Hans G. Despain, Monthly Review, September 2015:39-55). The 2008 economic crisis was caused mainly due to financialization of the economy and creation of asset bubbles that were byproducts of the crisis of over-accumulation and non-realization of capital in conventional economic sectors. Iran also is experiencing social complications that are partially related to financialization and the relative absence of investment in manufacturing. As reported by the Newspaper Etemad (Nov 22, 2016), in the last 10 years, 73 percent of the financial resources was invested in non-productive economic sectors.
 
In the view of an Iranian economist, Parrviz Sedagat, the present crisis in Iran, even though partly caused by factors such as international sanctions and geopolitical crisis in the region, is "basically, a crisis of accumulation in a capitalist economy." Its outcome has been relocation of capital from industrial to financial and commercial segments. Financial activities in Iran take place in two official and unofficial sectors. The first sphere covers institutions such as the central bank, stock market and insurance companies. Parallel to that, in the second segment, which is finance (its dealing is mainly in underground sphere), economic actions are not controlled by state institutions. Based on an official census, out of more than seven thousand financial institutions, about six thousand function without license and are not controlled by the assigned officials. From among the 50 largest economic institutions in Iran, 20 of them operate in the financial sector, and in the largest 100 companies, 57 percent and 25.5 percent of sales belong to banks and the financial institutions (Nagde Egtesade Siasi / pecritiqe.com).
 
The privatization trend in Iran is very selective and it is done only in the interest of powerful political groups. Many of the state owned economic institutions are transformed to the semi- private institutions and foundations, most of them under the control of the Islamic Revolutionary Guard Corps (IRGC). The high-ranking military officers have become economic partners with the bureaucratic and commercial bourgeoisie, and they all remain active under the ultimate control of a small ruling elite, headed by Khamenei. Based on a report by Wiki Leaks in 2010, economic institutions such as Telephone/cable company, Ghadir investing company, Isfehan Refinery, Saderat Bank, Tabriz Caterpillar and Sina Bank are among giant financial institutions that have been "purchased" by the IRGC.
 
In fact, in the process of transformation of state companies (particularly the financial institutions) to semi private entities that function under the control of the IRGC and are linked, in various ways, to the ruling quarters, the Iranian national assets are being ruined. The new "owners", in order to generate more profit, put a great deal of pressure on working people. Anti-workers measures such as late payment and downsizing (layoffs) are common in the privatized economic institutions. The "labor law reform" bill, underway, imposes further hard ship on workers and imposes more work with lower pay. This bill allows employers to easily cut entitlements and expel workers. The worse part for the working people is that the new "private" owners, in some cases due to the price increase of the properties and assets, put them up for sale and often the operating institutions end up being bankrupted and dissolved which adds to more unemployment and hardship for the working people.
 
For instance in the highly publicized (due to a very high volume of money involved), bankrupted economic institution of the financial institution Misan, 85 percent of the wasted loans belonged to only 12 individuals whose only purpose were to make profit  (The Newspaper Sharg, Nov 19, 2016). Recent protests by the workers in factories including Hapko factory, Aluminum Pars, Gulf Star Refinery of Bandar Abbas and Poly-Acryl, are in opposition to the anti-worker policies that result in further under-payment, cutting benefits and closing of many more factories and economic institutions. The neo-liberal policies pursued by the "moderate" government of Hasan Rouhani, in coordination with the hard-liners, do not contribute to constructive investments and productive economic performance inside the country, and it definitely undermines the living conditions for the majority of the working population.
 
The main issue here is that even in the case of "normalization" of the Iranian economy, it will remain, in various ways, connected to the imperialist system of outsourcing, and there will exist only a range of low-skilled operations profitable for big internal and external capitals without a system of organic relations between different industries of consumer and capital goods. In Iran like many other low-wage developing countries, the phenomenon of "super-exploitation" (transfer of surplus value by reducing wages below the value of labor-power) will intensify further. As the economic conditions in many other developing and even some western countries (e.g. Greece and Spain) indicate, when the finance industry dominates the already crisis-ridden capitalist economy, industrial production diminishes and the ideal all around expanded production becomes impossible. In fact, given that imperialistic relations and financialization of economy comprise the main features of the global political economy, and above all that a corrupt authoritarian regime reigns in Iran, one cannot see a bright future for economic justice in Iran.
 
As Judith Whitehead argues, "The capture of excess surplus-value by northern multinationals through outsourcing constitutes therefore the defining feature and mechanism of contemporary imperialism." In her view, contemporary imperialism, led by finance capital, is not only one of the major drivers of "secular stagnation," especially the relative lack of recent investment in manufacturing, but also of  impasse with primary accumulation that takes place, without the proportionate employment in large parts of the Global South. In 2012, the estimated size of the global reserve army of labor was 2.4 billion, while the total `active army' was estimated at 1.4 billion' which is almost 63 percent unemployment worldwide.  Around 79 percent of the global workforce now is located in low-wage countries and accumulation has not been followed by expanded production in many parts of the world (Judith Whitehead, Monthly Review, November 2016, 37-52).
 
In the past 40 years, there has been a defining shift, worldwide, in the movement of manufacturing industry from the Global North to the Global South and an increase in the share of industrial employment in the developing countries (83 percent in 2012 compared to 52 percent in the 1980s). In the same period, "the share of foreign investment in developing and transitional economies rose from 33 percent in 2006 to 51 percent by 2010." The multinational monopolies that are located mainly in the Western countries have decided to shift production to parts of the globe with the lowest unit labor costs and, under the system of "global labor arbitrage" (as the key element of the contemporary imperialist system), they exploit the workers in the periphery countries along the course of "unequal exchange based on a worldwide hierarchy of wages." Based on this "super exploitative" relation, enormous profits (often 50 percent or more on the export price of their products) are extracted by the Global North, "through process of value capture, as opposed to value creation" (Suwandi and Foster, Monthly Review, July-August, 2016: 124-125).
 
Since the nuclear accord between Iran and the 6 world powers a few years ago, international investors are coming back and, based on official report, so far 127 economic agreements have been made and 64 economic projects by the foreign companies have started activities (Donyay-eEqtesad.com, January 19, 2017). These companies and a range of other joint or local projects will only concentrate in more profit making (and not necessarily, productive), mainly in service and commercial industries.  For this reason, no doubt, many in the ruling quarters and their private partners are in favor of continuation of neoliberal policies (privatization and deregulations for local and foreign investors) and are not concerned about the closing down of many local `inefficient" industries that result in soaring unemployment and deprivation in the society.
 
At the same time, many foreign investors also are not concerned about the undemocratic and repressive nature of the Iranian political system and the officials' authoritarian policies towards resentments and protests by many activists in the social movements. The regime negates all kinds of democratic rights and suppresses every kind of political dissent. It does not tolerate independent political organization, and activists in the social movements, including in labor and women's movements. Activists are often arrested, many tortured and some even executed. At these times many labor and social movement activists are in prison.
 
The two ruling factions, known as religious hardliners (under the command of the supreme spiritual leader, Ali Khamenei) and "moderates" (represented by political personalities such as the late Ali Akbar Hashemi Rafsanjani and the President Hassan Rouhani), still govern the country in an authoritarian manner. In the absence of transparency and democratic monitoring by the public, capital in Iran prefers to find its way to every possible economic (mostly non-productive) outlet. It is reported that every year around 17.5 billion dollars, almost half of oil income, leaves the country and most of the remaining is either absorbed by the bureaucratic capitalists, including military upper echelon personnel and their private partners. Capital flight, or its drive towards non-productive, commercial and financial industries, definitely undermines the normal accumulation and production of capital and social values in Iran. History indicates that unless a true democracy is not established and people are not able to control their socio-political destiny, social and economic justice will not emerge. A democratic revolution is imperative for the establishment of liberty and social justice in Iran.
 
 

--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV

The Winners and Losers Radio Show
7-9 AM Weekdays, The EPIC Radio Player Stream, 
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio:EPIC Radio -- Friday lineup -- documentary Films, Charleston update, and Sci-Fi Theater

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Eastern Panhandle Independent Community (EPIC) Radio
Post: EPIC Radio -- Friday lineup -- documentary Films, Charleston update, and Sci-Fi Theater
Link: http://www.enlightenradio.org/2017/02/epic-radio-friday-lineup-documentary.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

NYTimes: Feeling ‘Pressure All the Time’ on Europe’s Treadmill of Temporary Work

Feeling 'Pressure All the Time' on Europe's Treadmill of Temporary Work https://nyti.ms/2k5KCAm

Thursday, February 9, 2017

More Cuts or More Revenue to Address WV Budget Crisis [feedly]


http://www.wvpolicy.org/more-cuts-or-more-revenue-to-address-wv-budget-crisis/
----
More Cuts or More Revenue to Address WV Budget Crisis
// WV Center on Budget and Policy

Public News Service – The West Virginia Center on Budget and Policy is warning against trying to close the state's $600 million budget gap entirely or mostly through cuts. Governor Jim Justice wants to raise $450 million in new revenue – with about half of that coming from increased business taxes. Read.


----

Shared via my feedly newsfeed