Monday, January 28, 2019

Working Class Perspectives The Ghosts of Bisbee [feedly]


There is economics, and then their human consequences..

The Ghosts of Bisbee
https://workingclassstudies.wordpress.com/2019/01/28/the-ghosts-of-bisbee/

by Working Class Perspectives.

Bisbee '17 is a documentary about an Arizona town facing its ghosts.  In June 1917, when copper miners organized by the Industrial Workers of the World had gone on strike for two weeks, 1200 striking workers were rounded up and "deported" to New Mexico. The owner of the mine, the Phelps-Dodge Company, also owned the hospital, department store, library, newspaper, main hotel . . . in other words, Bisbee was a company town. In 1917, everyone had been forced to take a side, and only those on the company's side remained in Bisbee. Like many towns with one employer, family and community were torn apart by the strike and deportation. One hundred years later, as the film shows, the town reenacted the event.

Unfortunately, viewers will learn very little about the historical event from the film. Instead, we witness the former mining community recreate an event from the pseudo memories of transplants to Bisbee and the grandchildren of deported miners and armed deputies who rounded-up strikers and their families. Residents play the roles of strikers and deputies, reenacting the armed capture of peaceful strikers who were herded into the ballfield and then stuffed into freight cars.

As the community planned for the one-hundred-year celebration of the Bisbee Deportation, they chose a path common to American historical sites: create art, sing songs, and stage the event as a tourist attraction. The film shows community members trying to understand both sides: miners striking for more pay and safer working conditions and others who argued the company's perspective — that the IWW threatened the war effort as well as the livelihood of the town. To capture all sides, the usual tropes prevail. The "Mexican family" is represented by a young man whose mom was deported to Mexico when he was seven and who "nurtured himself" growing up. The woman posing as his mother in the enactment is a Republican Country Clerk who views her acting as "kinda like a novella." However, labor history is not a soap opera. Bisbee '17 shows us how the reenactment can be cathartic as town therapy, but a closer look at Arizona's recent history of deportation shows the ghosts were not exorcized.

The Bisbee Deportation has been well documented in newspaper articles; local, state and federal government officials' correspondence; and court proceedings from law suits filed by the deportees and charges against participants in the deportation. Sheriff Harry C. Wheeler had deputized the Citizens' Protective League or Loyalty Leaguers to roundup strikers, strike sympathizers, and others from their homes, restaurants, stores, and on the street. On July 12, 1917, they were loaded onto twenty-four cattle and box cars and sent to Columbus, New Mexico, where they were met by armed guards who kept them from detraining. The box cars of people were then taken to Hermanas, New Mexico — all without adequate food or water. Later they were returned to Columbus, held by military authorities, and eventually released, but not allowed to return to Bisbee.  Civil and criminal suits were filed against the Phelps-Dodge, persons involved in the kidnapping, and the El Paso and Southwestern Railroad for providing the trains for the deportation. A financial compromise was reached, and no trial was held. Although both federal and state charges were filed against the sheriff and government and business officials for their participation, no one was punished.

The labor history of the Bisbee Deportation may have been forgotten by current Arizona residents, but we don't have to look back a century to find an Arizona sheriff deputizing a posse to assist in the deportation of unwanted immigrant workers. Maricopa County Sheriff Joe Arpaio, who held that post for 24 years, established the "illegal immigration operations posse" in 2011 to round up undocumented immigrants working in construction, landscaping, or restaurants as well as people who were walking or driving to home or work. Although Arpaio claimed these raids were "crime sweeps," few of the immigrants arrested had criminal records. Along with county sheriffs, members of the posse participated in immigration sweeps targeting and terrorizing Latino communities in Maricopa County.

Protests against the raids were met with same rationale as the "Law of Necessity" used to justify the Bisbee deportation: the immigration system is broken, the federal government is not responding, so the sheriff took control. Federal funding from ICE's partnership initiatives to work with local law enforcement, the 287(g) agreement, lured local authorities across the county to participate in immigration law enforcement, moreover huge profits are being made by privately-owned detention centers. Over the last decade hundreds of immigrants were held in detention centers, separated from their families, and deported. Remarkably, the organizers of the Bisbee reenactment cast someone who had worked in the private prison and deportation industry to play the sheriff, linking the two events.

Just as in the Bisbee Deportation, lawsuits were filed and eventually the class action lawsuit, Ortega Melendres vs. Arpaio found the sheriff had targeted Latino drivers and passengers in violation of the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. The court mandated changes that the sheriff ignored, and his posse continued to enforce immigration after losing the federal 287(g) agreement to work with ICE. Arpaio was found in contempt of court, but before he could be sentenced Trump pardoned him. Like Sheriff Wheeler, Sheriff Arpaio was never punished for his crimes.

Trump's policy of zero tolerance has deported many workers and broken up families, including many long-time residents, homeowners, and respected members in their communities. We have witnessed hundreds of asylum seekers deported without due process, families separated, and parents and children detained in privately-owned detention centers. Recently the Southwest Key Program, the largest private operator of shelters for migrant children, came under federal investigation for misappropriating government funds. Many still find deportation to be good for business.

A century from now, will Arizonans stage another play about deportations? Will the actors and residents play migrants and ICE?  Sheriff Arpaio and members of his posse? Will some play the parents and children separated at the border or dragged from their homes during the early morning? Will we, too,  tell this story using a passive voice — "men died," "life went on," "mistakes were made"? Clearly, Bisbee and the state have not exorcised their ghosts.

Mary Romero and Eric Margolis

Mary Romero is a Professor at Arizona State University and the author of several books on domestic workers and on intersectionality, including Introducing Intersectionality. She is President of the American Sociological Association.

Eric Margolis is a visual sociologist and the author of numerous works on the hidden curriculum in higher education. Most of his work can be found on his website. 


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Sunday, January 27, 2019

The World Economy Just Can’t Escape Its Low-Growth, Low-Inflation Rut [feedly]

The World Economy Just Can't Escape Its Low-Growth, Low-Inflation Rut
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/01/27/upshot/world-economy-low-growth-low-interest-deflation.html

Fears of an imminent recession, which caused major turbulence in financial markets at the end of 2018 and beginning of 2019, have eased a bit.

That's the good news. The bad news is what that episode exposed.

For much of 2018, it appeared that the world economy was finally getting out of the rut it had been stuck in for the decade since the global financial crisis. But it now looks as if the era of persistently low growth, low inflation and low interest rates isn't over after all.

In the past week alone, the European Central Bank said that economic risks had "moved to the downside," and the Bank of Japan cut its projections for inflation.

The Federal Reserve will hold a policy meeting Tuesday and Wednesday, and is likely to leave its interest rate target unchanged. Its leaders could also discuss their broader strategy for making monetary policy, which may include keeping more of their giant portfolio of bonds — accumulated during its years of stimulus efforts — than analysts had once expected.

ADVERTISEMENT

Despite some promising signs of vitality during much of last year, issues that have dogged the world economy for the last decade — an aging work force in many of the biggest economies, weak growth in productivity, excessive global savings and industrial capacity, and a shortage of worldwide demand — haven't disappeared.

That helps explain why American workers' wages have been rising relatively slowly despite a low unemployment rate. And it makes for a perilous time: Low growth rates mean the economy could slip into recession more easily, and low interest rates mean central bankers would find themselves with less powerful tools to lessen the pain of a future downturn.

"This shows that the forces that are restraining many economies are a lot harder to contend with and more pervasive than many people were hoping or believing," said Roberto Perli, a partner in Cornerstone Macro. "It's bad news for the work force's earnings prospects in many countries and for those who hope for a reversal of the growing inequality trend that has been in place for many years."

Consider that markets went haywire in the final weeks of 2018 in significant part because of fears that the Federal Reserve was raising rates by more than the economy could handle. Jerome Powell, the Fed chairman, played a big role in fueling a stock market rebound when, on Jan. 4, he pledged that the Fed would adjust policy "quickly and flexibly" as conditions warranted.

His predecessor, Janet Yellen, went so far as to say recently that "it's very possible we may have seen the last interest rate hike of this cycle." But what does it mean when a mere 2.4 percent interest rate — the rough level of the Fed's target after a December increase — is enough to risk breaking the economy?



The story is even more pessimistic in the European Union, where interest rates are slightly below zero and yet growth is faltering.

With the world economy heavily reliant on stimulus to achieve even meager growth, there is little cushion for a negative shock. In particular, it makes the United States more vulnerable to recession caused by any number of factors, including government shutdowns and trade wars.

Adam Posen, president of the Peterson Institute for International Economics, said, "If this is what growth and investment look like when there is relatively loose monetary and fiscal policy — especially in the U.S. — the underlying strength just isn't there.

"That doesn't mean policy is ineffective or ill-advised. Things would be much worse, unnecessarily, if policy tightened a lot. But it is scary to think of the world economy absent macro support," meaning the stimulus provided by low interest rates and large deficits.

There is the risk of a nasty feedback loop. The low-growth trap of the last decade — and the resulting stagnant incomes — might have contributed to dysfunctional politics in nations including Britain, Italy and the United States. Those dysfunctional politics in turn can create new risks of economic disruption, as we saw in the recent shutdown standoff in Washington.

Last year began with signs of a new economic era. In early February, the stock market was falling amid concerns that the United States economy was overheating; that wages and prices would start rising too fast; and that the Fed would need to raise interest rates faster to rein things in. Shifts in bond markets suggested investors were betting on higher future inflation, and on higher interest rates in the distant future than in the near future.

For the first time in ages, most of the major advanced and emerging economies were enjoying simultaneous growth surges. As 2018 progressed, inflation in the United States finally moved back up to the 2 percent level that the Federal Reserve targets, and the Fed's pattern of once-a-quarter rate increases became mostly a nonevent in markets.


ADVERTISEMENT

It was starting to look as if the old economic rules — that low unemployment would translate into higher inflation, that large government deficits would crowd out private investment — were becoming true again.

But in the sell-off that knocked about 10 percent off the S&P 500 from the start of October to Christmas Eve, long-term interest rates fell by more than half a percentage point. Bond prices pointed to lower future inflation, as did plunging oil prices.

The expected annual inflation rate in the next decade — reflected in the price of inflation-protected bonds — rose to 2.18 percent in April 2018 from 1.66 percent in June 2017. It hovered in the 2.18 range for a few months, then plunged in late October to a recent low of 1.7 percent.

And prices in futures markets reflected expectations that the Fed would enact no more interest rate increases in 2019. Even as the consensus view of Fed officials at their December meeting was that two interest rate increases were on tap for 2019, markets were essentially flashing a signal of "Oh no, you don't."

At the same time, weaker growth in China — a reported 6.6 percent in 2018, still strong by American or European standards — removes a source of strength for the global economy. China is trying to wean itself off debt-driven growth.

"Chinese policymakers are well aware they probably have a credit bubble and have tried to be more temperate in response to the current slowdown," said Julia Coronado, president of MacroPolicy Perspectives. "But it is hard to accept low growth potential. We see the political instability that that brings around the world, and China is now faced with the uncomfortable decision of re-initiating stimulus or living with notably slower growth."

The world economy is not in crisis. Low growth is better than no growth — or outright contraction.

But what the last few months have made clear is that the forces that have held back the global economy for the last 11 years are not temporary, and have not gone away. And that, in turn, makes the world uncommonly vulnerable to a bout of bad luck or bad policy.

The low-growth world was not just a phase. It's the new reality beneath every macroeconomic question and debate for the foreseeable future.

Neil Irwin is a senior economics correspondent for The Upshot. He previously wrote for The Washington Post and is the author of "The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire." @Neil_Irwin • Facebook

READ 53 COMMENTS
 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Friday, January 25, 2019

Fwd: Government Shutdown - temporary funding deal (thank you!)



---------- Forwarded message ---------
From: Chip Shannon <cshannon@aflcio.org>
Date: Fri, Jan 25, 2019 at 4:36 PM
Subject: Government Shutdown - temporary funding deal (thank you!)
To: John Case <jcase4218@gmail.com>


To:     All State Federations and Area and Central Labor Councils
Re:    Government Shutdown - temporary funding deal

THANK YOU! Because of your work - including nearly 25,000 calls to senate offices and almost 50 collective actions held just today - the White House just announced a deal to temporarily re-open the government. 



This is what we know about the deal:
  • votes in the Senate, then the House, may happen as early as this evening,
  • the deal will fund the government through February 15,
  • federal employees will receive backpay, but
  • there are currently no solutions for the hundreds of thousands of federal contractors who have lost a month of work.
For now, we encourage you to take the following actions:
  • please work to keep pressure on the White House and Congress to pass a permanent funding bill by February 15
  • please continue to circulate our toll-free hotlines (Senate: 866-803-8830 & House: 855-976-9914) so union members can contact their members of Congress
  • please call the 52 senators who voted yesterday for the clean bill to re-open the government
  • continue to use our toolkit (go.aflcio.org/ShutdownToolkit) for social graphics, content and resources
In solidarity,
Chip

--
Chip Shannon | AFL-CIO
Assistant Director | Political, Electoral & Issue Mobilization



--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Senator Warren’s plan to tax the ultrawealthy is a smart idea whose time has come. [feedly]

Senator Warren's plan to tax the ultrawealthy is a smart idea whose time has come.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2019/01/24/senator-warrens-plan-tax-ultrawealthy-is-smart-idea-whose-time-has-come/

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Progressives must end the shutdown. But we can’t fight on Trump’s preferred turf. [feedly]

Bernstein nails a key aspect of the shutdown -- this is a genuine, serious,  political and institutional crisis.  And its bigger than Trump, as urgent as the need for his ASAP removal from office may be.

Progressives must end the shutdown. But we can't fight on Trump's preferred turf.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2019/01/24/yes-progressives-must-fight-end-shutdown-we-must-also-get-off-trumps-preferred-turf-fast/

 Were he writing op-eds today, Tolstoy might point out that all shutdowns are dumb, but that this one is the dumbest.

What makes it so dumb? Do I really need to answer that? Suffice it to say that this Congress, which can't agree on anything, agreed to appropriate the money needed to avoid a shutdown, until President Trump swooped in at the last minute and blocked the deal, based on pressure from his base to "build the wall." No one, including Trump, knows what "the wall" is, beyond a campaign slogan.

True, spineless Senate Republicans won't stand up to Trump on this, but the fact remains: If one stubborn, ill-informed person can shut down the government of the world's largest economy and keep it that way for more than a month, something very important is very broken. And it's going to take a lot more than ending the shutdown to fix it.

For now, 800,000 furloughed or unpaid government workers are feeling the direct brunt of this idiocy, but consider that Trump's chief economist, Kevin Hassett, warned that the shutdown is doing so much damage to the economy that it could mean that the real gross domestic product growth rate this quarter will be zero. As I'll explain in a moment, I suspect he's wrong, although quarterly numbers are volatile, so you never know.

But what is Hassett saying here? Is he trying to send his boss a message? Trump explicitly owns the shutdown, so I can't be the only one having trouble wrapping the aging noggin around his administration complaining about its effect. They could stop it by the time I finish writing this missive! Hassett warning about the shutdown's effect is like a mugger warning you that if he doesn't cease and desist, you might get hurt.

Ironically, if the government remains partly shut down through March — an unprecedented disaster — we won't learn the GDP growth rate for the current quarter because the Commerce Department won't release it. But let's think about the macroeconomics of this a bit.

Last seen, real GDP growth was trending at a 3 percent rate, goosed by a tight labor market generating moderate real wage gains, which in turn support solid consumer spending. Because such spending is 68 percent of our GDP, that's a decent tail wind. True, a variety of head winds, including higher interest rates, weaker home sales, slower global growth and, yes, team Trump repeatedly kicking the ball in our own goal — trade war, shutdown — are expected to shave maybe one-half a percentage point off the trend (more if the shutdown persists). That gets us into the 2 percent range, although technical factors could slice a bit more off the rate (in recent years, first quarter GDP has been over-adjusted down for seasonal effects).

That's not zero, but again, these numbers — if they come out! — are noisy, so who knows? Also, as Hassett noted, some of this lost growth comes back when the shutdown ends and government spending ramps up more than it would have otherwise.

Is there any way out of this seemingly never-ending dumbness?

I'm not just talking about ending the shutdown, although that's the first imperative. Perhaps the Senate votes that are scheduled for Thursday, although not expected to pass, will be the beginning of the end. If not, and I don't say this lightly, I'd urge Transportation Security Agency workers to engage in either a massive sickout or a strike, the latter of which would be illegal and is thus not without risk (although working without pay shouldn't be legal either). Shut down air travel and you un-shutdown the government in about an hour, I'd bet. I acknowledge that it's easy to tell other people to engage in civil disobedience, although I guarantee you, I wouldn't be the only progressive to join that picket line.

But what I'm talking about — and what so many of us are longing for — is to get away from arguments about "the wall" and whether and where Trump will give his State of the Union address (because of the expected content of that speech, I can think of no less pressing question), to the policy debates we're not having. We're existentially threatened by climate change. That's partly a function of inadequately regulated capitalism that's also delivering monopolistic dominance in key industries (tech, health, retail) and oligarchic levels of income and especially wealth inequality. Our pay-to-play political system maps such wealth concentration onto the least representative politics and policies that many of us have seen in our lifetimes.

Trump and Brexit and authoritarian leaders worldwide offer easy answers to these challenges: It's the elites, it's the immigrants, it's people who don't look like you. More often than not, they do so while appropriating even more wealth for themselves, their families and their donors.

Let's be very clear about this: Such leadership loves the fight between "Nancy and Don" about the State of the Union. This is the only type of fight Trump's knows. Beyond serving up tax cuts and deregulation to their donor base, and the "wall-that-Mexico-will-fund" to their political base, they got nothing.

Again, ending the shutdown is the first order of business. But at the same time, progressives must cordon off the crazy and start intensely facilitating and planning for the essential shift in political power. I've been trying to help on the policy front and will continue to do so.

But we all need to row in the same direction on this one, by which I decidedly don't mean we have to agree on the way forward. Let's argue about Medicare for More vs. Medicare-for-all, and job subsidies vs. job guarantees, and where to set the top marginal rate. But every minute spent fighting on Trump's turf is a minute wasted in the greatest cause of this moment: the one to revitalize representative democracy.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Senator Warren’s plan to tax the ultrawealthy is a smart idea whose time has come. [feedly]

Senator Warren's plan to tax the ultrawealthy is a smart idea whose time has come.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2019/01/24/senator-warrens-plan-tax-ultrawealthy-is-smart-idea-whose-time-has-come/

Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D-Mass.) has just introduced a tax idea this country desperately needs: a tax on high-end wealth. It's an idea that's well-crafted for our time, one that promises to add fairness to an unfair tax code, raise significant, much-needed revenue and push back on the historically high level of wealth concentration in the United States.

Here's the plan, which, for the record, is extremely simple to explain, an advantage when it comes to tax policy: Wealth over $50 million would be taxed at 2 percent; wealth over $1 billion would face an extra 1 percent tax. "Wealth" is defined as net worth — the value of assets minus any debts.

That's it. It is projected that the tax would raise about $2.75 trillion in revenue over 10 years. To get a sense of that magnitude, recall that the Trump tax cuts lost less revenue (just under $2 trillion) than this tax allegedly gains. That's a lot of tax progressivity pushing back on the highly regressive Trump cuts.

According to wealth scholars Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman (S&Z), less than 0.1 percent of households (the top tenth of the top 1 percent), about 75,000 of them, would face this new tax, which raises the question: How could such a small tax on such a tiny base raise so much money? The answer speaks to the extent of wealth concentration.

S&Z find that since the 1970s, the share of total wealth held by the top 0.1 percent grew by a factor of almost three, from 7 percent in the late 1970s to 20 percent in recent years. Moreover, the top's gain has been everyone else's loss: The bottom 90 percent of households have gone from holding 35 percent of wealth in the 1970s to 25 percent today. In other words, the top 0.1 percent's wealth holdings aren't that much less than those of the bottom 90 percent.

It's notable in this context that wealth tends to be about twice as concentrated as income, in part because it feeds on itself. The "miracle of compounding" is a tremendous force for those sitting on a large pile of large assets. It's also terribly skewed away from minorities. As Valerie Wilson has shown, the black/white median income ratio is about 60 percent. For net worth, it's 10 percent.

Narrowing the scope within the top 0.1 percent to the 75,000 households with net worth above $50 million yields a base of more than $9 trillion, of which about $2.5 trillion would face the billionaire's surcharge of an extra 1 percent. In other words, the small tax delivers a large revenue payload because there's so much wealth concentrated in that rarefied bit of the stratosphere.

The plan's $2.75 trillion score implies the ability to capture a lot of wealth that's sheltered from taxation, so it must be robust to tax avoidance and evasion, of which there's a lot among this crowd (remember the "Panama Papers"?). One important feature in this regard is that no assets are given favorable treatment: All the assets of households above the threshold are included in the net worth measurement, regardless of where in the world such assets reside.

To meet this goal, the plan includes a significant increase in the Internal Revenue Service's enforcement budget, a minimum audit rate for the wealthiest taxpayers, a 40 percent "exit tax" on those above the $50 million threshold who renounce their citizenship and — among the most important parts of this — anti-evasion mechanisms to share information with foreign governments. Still, these are folks with the best tax lawyers money can buy, so the score assumes that households subject to the tax find ways to reduce their liability by 15 percent.

All that said, as S&Z themselves recently pointed out in a must-read commentary, revenue isn't the only rationale for such progressive taxation. It's also about "regulating inequality and the market economy" and, even more so, "safeguarding democracy against oligarchy." In that context, they make two critical points. First, top U.S. tax rates are much lower than they've ever been in our history, and, second, despite fact-free rhetoric to the contrary, there's no negative growth impact from high top rates, either here or in other advanced economies.

Still, you can be sure we'll hear massive sob stories about how the Warren high-net-worth tax will crush capital investment. Don't believe it, for at least three reasons. First, the historical record fails to show a correlation between changes in taxes, including those on capital gains (income derived from wealth) and business investment. Second, the Trump tax cuts, which were explicitly targeted at investment, have very little to show for it. Third, even if there were a negative effect, we're talking about tax rates of 2 percent or 3 percent, so any such "elasticity" would be barely tweaked by this tax.

S&Z's sage warnings on inequality and oligarchy raise what is perhaps the most important attribute of this idea: the taxation of wealth, something we do almost none of in this country. Especially when it comes to the rich and their contemporary portfolios, this makes no sense. We tax income, of course, but for the wealthy, income streams flow from wealth in the form of interest, dividends and capital gains. True, we tax those forms of incomes, but at favorable rates, privileging wealth-derived income over work-derived income. In fact, S&Z find that the Warren tax would raise taxes paid by the wealthiest households as a share of net worth from 3.2 percent to 4.3 percent, compared with 7.2 percent for households in the bottom 99 percent. One way to further close the remaining regressive gap between those rates would be to lower the threshold of the plan from $50 million to something like $20 million or $30 million.

But perhaps the main reason to bring Warren's plan to fruition is because, as Zucman writes, "For the rich, wealth begets power." This is especially the case in our pay-to-play politics, where the high wealth concentrations documented above buy the policies that block ideas just like this one.

In other words, to give Warren the last word, the economy — more precisely, the tax code — is rigged. True, this plan isn't going to become law anytime too soon, but those of us longing to de-rig the economy are in it for the long haul. So, thanks, Senator, for providing us with an inspiring idea whose time has come.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

How a Basic Income can Battle the 8 Giants of a Faltering Economy [feedly]

How a Basic Income can Battle the 8 Giants of a Faltering Economy
https://www.globalpolicyjournal.com/blog/25/01/2019/how-basic-income-can-battle-8-giants-faltering-economy

The post-1945 income distribution system is irretrievably broken, threatening the market economy. And traditional redistributive tools such as direct taxes, collective bargaining, and labor regulations cannot put things right.

In 1942, William Beveridge issued an epoch-defining report that established a model for welfare states in the post-war era. He recognized that the old social protection system had broken down and that it was "time for revolution, not for patching." The challenge, Beveridge said, was to slay five giants: disease, idleness, ignorance, squalor, and want.

Today, it is the post-1945 income distribution system that has broken down irretrievably, threatening economic failure and jeopardizing what Klaus Schwab calls "Globalization 4.0." Today we must fight eight new giants. To do so, we urgently need a twenty-first-century income distribution system in which a basic income plays a central role. Such a system might not slay today's eight giants, but it would significantly weaken them. 

The first giant is inequality – the huge growth in income and wealth disparities within countries that goes well beyond what is captured by measures such as the Gini coefficient. An increasing share of total income is being captured as rent by owners of physical, financial, and so-called intellectual property. Meanwhile, real wages have stagnated or fallen, and ever more people are falling through widening holes in the social safety net. Traditional redistributive tools such as direct taxes, collective bargaining, and labor regulations cannot reverse these structural shifts, however much those on the left might wish. 

What is needed is a new income distribution system that restores the market economy rather than distorting it. By recycling rents currently taken by the plutocracy and elite to everybody, a basic income paid as a common dividend would be the anchor of a reformed system. Contrary to what some critics assert, a basic income would not be regressive. Paid equally and quasi-universally from rentier income, it would necessarily be progressive. 

The second threat is economic insecurity. The welfare state was supposed to insure workers against contingent risks and shocks. But it is failing because of reduced social insurance coverage, flexible labor markets, and widespread technological disruption, among other causes. Moreover, today's economic insecurity is characterized by uncertainty about the future rather than known risks. People feel threatened by "unknown unknowns" that, by definition, cannot be insured against. In an open, globalized economy, only a basic income can guarantee basic security.

The next giant, and closely related to the first two, is debt. Millions are living on the financial edge, with unpaid rents, utility bills, and high-cost credit cards. A significant rise in interest rates or an economic downturn could trigger an avalanche of distress. True, a basic income would not solve the debt problem, but pilot projects show that when people know a regular amount is coming in, they are likelier to pay down debts and gain greater control of their finances.

Fourth, and again related, is stress. This is a global pandemic, with an increasing number of people suffering from depression, mental illness, suicidal tendencies, and physical ailments linked to job pressures, insecurity, inequality, and feelings of inadequacy among many people who perceive themselves to be just "licking at the window" of consumerism. A basic income would not cure the stress pandemic, but it would reduce its intensity and prevalence.

The fifth giant is the ever-growing precariat – the millions of people who face a bits-and-pieces life of unstable, often unpaid labor, having to rely on money wages alone. They are supplicants, without what sociologists call "agency," who depend on discretionary favors from bureaucrats, family members, and occasional employers. A basic income would offer much-needed respite to these people and make them feel less like beggars.

Robots are the sixth danger. I am skeptical about the alarming predictions of tech gurus and economists who believe that artificial intelligence and technological wizardry will soon lead to mass displacement of humans. Still, the ongoing tech revolution is undoubtedly disruptive and, although it may accelerate growth, it will continue to intensify inequalities. A basic income would help to share the gains more widely.

The threat of extinction from global warming and the ecological catastrophe is the seventh giant that must be confronted, and it may prove to be the most decisive in mobilizing support for a basic income. The threat must be combated with new and increased eco-taxes or levies. Returning the proceeds of "green" levies to people as equal common dividends – a form of basic income – would turn unpopular regressive measures into progressive ones. This is already happening in Canada, led by a successful initiative in British Columbia. What's more, our research shows that a basic income would tilt economic activity toward personal services, community, and voluntary work, reducing the yawning "care deficit" in aging societies.

The eighth giant blocking the way to a flourishing, inclusive economic system is populism, which in some cases is fast becoming neo-fascism. Support for populists also has grown dramatically in Europe, no doubt owing to chronic economic inequality, insecurity, debt, stress, and anger. A basic income would make many more people feel like valued citizens with a stake in democracy.

I have worked on basic income policies for three decades, and I have been involved in piloting variants on four continents. As the economic, political, and environmental threats to our future multiply, rolling out a universal individual basic income is more important than ever.

 

 

Guy Standing, Professorial research associate, School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London.

This first appeared on the World Economic Forum's Agenda blog.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed