Monday, June 18, 2018

Krugman: Thinking About a Trade War (Very Wonkish) [feedly]

Thinking About a Trade War (Very Wonkish)
https://www.nytimes.com/2018/06/17/opinion/thinking-about-a-trade-war-very-wonkish.html

Until fairly recently, I didn't really think we were going to have a trade war. What I thought would happen, instead, was a bit of kabuki: America's major trading partners would make cosmetic concessions – perhaps with some lucrative payoffs to Trump businesses on the side – that would let Trump proclaim a "win", and trade would go on much as before.

The reason I expected this relatively benign outcome wasn't that Trump would get or take good advice. It was, instead, the expectation that big money would talk: corporations have invested trillions based on the assumption that an open world trading system, permitting value-added chains that sprawl across national borders, was going to be a permanent fixture of the environment. A trade war would disrupt all these investments, stranding a lot of capital, and I thought big business would get either manage to get that message through to Trump or at least get it through to Republicans in Congress, who would act to limit his room for maneuver.

But these political considerations look a lot less compelling now than they did a few months ago. With Gary Cohn gone, it's not clear that big business has any real pipeline into the White House (OK, polluters have an open line to Scott Pruitt, and predatory lenders a line to Mick Mulvaney, but these aren't the groups who will stand up against trade war.) And Congressional Republicans, terrified of the Trump base, have proved unwilling to take a stand on anything, even if big money is at stake.

Meanwhile, trade decisions are being made at Trump's whim, without input from anyone who knows anything about trade economics (Peter Navarro thinks he understands the economics, which is even worse.)

ADVERTISEMENT

Oh, and Trump's version of diplomacy – not just trade actions, but the systematic praise of brutal dictators and disdain for democratic leaders – has created a very angry world out there. Nobody out there wants to give Trump even the appearance of a win, and elected leaders would be punished by their voters if they did.

So a serious trade war now looks very possible, and it's time to think about what it might mean.

There are, I think, three main questions:

1. How high might tariffs go?

2. How much would this reduce world trade?

3. How costly would the trade war be?

These are all slightly tricky questions, as I'll explain. But there's a pretty good case that an all-out trade war could mean tariffs in the 30-60 percent range; that this would lead to a very large reduction in trade, maybe 70 percent; but that the overall cost to the world economy would be smaller than I think many people imagine, maybe a 2-3% reduction in world GDP.

This last calculation, however, doesn't take account of the disruptive effects of deglobalization: some people would actually gain, but a lot of people, very much including large groups and many communities in the U.S., would take big hits, especially in the short-to-medium run.

How high might tariffs go?

What do we mean by a trade war? In the current context, we mean a situation in which the world's economies, taking their lead from the U.S., abandon the rules and agreements that currently constrain their tariffs and start setting tariffs unilaterally in their perceived self-interest.

E

ADVERTISEMENT

The problematic word, of course, is "perceived". On trade, as on other subjects, Trump's perceptions generally don't seem very tethered to reality. And to be fair, the economic policy performance of other major players, notably the EU, hasn't been noteworthy for the triumph of clear economic thinking.

Still, there have been a number of attempts to model trade war over the years, relying on one of two approaches. The first is to imagine that governments actually do maximize national income, or perhaps an objective function that gives extra weight to well-organized interest groups. The second appeals to the historical experience of the world before international trade agreements became the norm. Fortunately, these approaches suggest similar tariff levels.

On the first approach: any country large enough that it can affect world prices of the goods it exports, the goods it imports, or both, has an "optimal tariff" greater than zero. The reason is that by limiting its trade, such a country can improve its terms of trade: the price of its exports relative to the price of its imports. This raises real income, other things equal. And the optimal tariff trades off the costs of reduced trade – e.g., the cost of producing goods domestically when they could be purchased more cheaply abroad – against the gains from improved terms of trade.

The problem is that if everyone does this, you get the costs of reduced trade without the benefit of improved terms of trade, because other countries are doing unto you the same thing you're trying to do unto them. So you end up in a situation of "optimal tariff warfare", which is actually more like an arms race than a shooting war, in the sense that there's (usually) no victor and no resolution, just a lot of wasted resources.

So how do you estimate the effects of optimal tariff warfare? You need a "computable general equilibrium" model of world trade – something that shows how production and trade flows depend on tariff rates, calibrated to match the actual data. Then you have to find an equilibrium (a Nash equilibrium, for readers of "A Beautiful Mind") in which each country is charging its optimal tariff given what everyone else is doing.

There are many assumptions and imputations involved, with the results depending a lot on how easily goods from one country can be substituted for goods from another – a parameter that's hard to estimate. Still, there are several fairly recent efforts: Ossa finds that a trade war would, under his favored assumptions, lead to tariffs of nearly 60 percent, while Nicita et al, using slightly different assumptions, estimate a rise in tariffs of 32 percentage points from current levels.

ADVERTISEMENT

If this seems too abstract, we can look at history: the Smoot-Hawley tariff, the last great protectionist move by the U.S. before we created the system of trade agreements, pushed tariffs up to around 45 percent on "dutiable" imports (tariffs were so high that most imports involved goods that for whatever reason faced no tariff at all.) You may wonder why I don't say 59 percent, which was the peak reached in 1932; but that was sort of an accident, even higher than protectionists wanted, the result of deflation that pushed up the rate of protection for those goods whose tariffs were specified in dollars per unit rather than percentages.

So both history and quantitative models suggest that a trade war would lead to quite high tariffs, with rates of more than 40 percent quite likely.

How much would trade decline?

For any given tariff rate, the amount of trade reduction depends on the elasticity of import demand – the percentage fall in imports for every one percent rise in their price. Such elasticities are hard to estimate, because we don't get many natural experiments. (Fluctuations in exchange rates change import prices, but those only give us an idea of short-run effects, and everyone believes that long-run elasticities are much bigger.)

As best I can read the literature, consensus estimates for the elasticity of import demand are something like 3 or 4, but there's not much certainty here.

If we really believe in optimal tariff warfare, however, the effects of the war on trade volumes are surprisingly insensitive to the precise value of the elasticity. Why? Because the optimal tariff also depends on the elasticity. If foreigners can easily substitute away from your goods, the optimal tariff is fairly low; if they can't, it's high. So high elasticities mean low tariffs, low elasticities mean high tariffs, and the decline in trade is similar. (See this little write-up.)

My back of the envelope calculations suggest that we might be looking at around a 70 percent fall in trade for a wide range of cases. I'd be happy to be corrected by trade modelers if that's wrong.

But if that's right, we're talking about a really big rollback of world trade. Figure 1 shows world trade (exports plus imports) as a share of world GDP back to 1950; a 70 percent reduction would bring us roughly back to 1950s levels. If Trump is really taking us into a trade war, the global economy is going to get a lot less global.

ADVERTISEMENT
Image
Figure 1CreditWorld BankHow big are the costs?

There has historically been a lot of hype about the evils of protectionism – Smoot-Hawley caused the Great Depression, and all that. It's also tempting to assume that because the Trumpist argument for trade war is so stupid, Trump trade policies must be totally disastrous.

But I've always ended up being really sorry when I let my political feelings override what my economic analysis says. And simple trade models, while they do say that trade wars are bad, don't say that they're catastrophic.

To do this right, we should use one of those computable general equilibrium models I mentioned above. These suggest substantial but not huge losses – 2 or 3 percent of GDP. What I'd like to do is offer a bit of intuition about why those losses aren't bigger, then explain why a trade war would nonetheless be highly disruptive.

To do this, I'll exploit a dirty little secret of trade theory: while ultimately stories about trade have to be general equilibrium, that is, they must make sure that you've kept track of all markets simultaneously, trade policy analysis using partial equilibrium – ordinary supply and demand – usually gets you more or less the right answer.

So let's think about the demand for imports as if it were an ordinary demand curve, with the costs of a tariff coming in the form of lost consumer surplus (Figure 2). Those who remember their Econ 101 will know that the costs of a market distortion normally take the form of a rough triangle (rough because the demand curve doesn't have to be a straight line, but that's a fairly minor detail.) That's because the first unit of imports lost has approximately zero cost, because people are indifferent at the margin between that unit and a domestic product, but the last unit lost imposes a cost equal to the tariff rate, because that's how much more people would have been willing to pay for the import. And the average cost of reduced imports is halfway between these values.
Image
Figure 2






So when a tariff drives up the price of imports to consumers, leading them to buy fewer imported goods, the welfare loss will be roughly
Loss = fall in imports * ½ tariff rate

Now, the U.S. currently spends 15 percent of GDP on imports. Suppose we end up with a trade-war tariff of 40 percent, and (as I've been suggesting) a 70 percent decline in trade. Then the welfare loss is 20% * 0.7*15, or 2.1% of GDP.

That's not a small number, but it's not that huge either: at the bottom of the Great Recession, CBO estimates that we were operating 6 percent below potential GDP. Of course that loss was temporary, while a trade war might be forever.

But these net welfare costs may miss the real point, which is disruption.

Disruption

The U.S. currently exports about 12 percent of GDP. Not all of that is domestic value added, because some components are imported. But there's still a lot of the economy, maybe 9 or 10 percent, engaged in production for foreign markets. And if we have the kind of trade war I've been envisaging, something like 70 percent of that part of the economy – say, 9 or 10 million workers – will have to start doing something else. And there would be a multiplier effect on many communities now built around export industries, which would lose service jobs too.

This is just the flip side of the "China shock" story: even if you believe that the rapid growth of Chinese exports didn't cost the U.S. jobs on net, it changed the composition and location of employment, producing a lot of losers along the way. And the "Trump shock" that would come from a trade war would be an order of magnitude bigger.

You can see hints of what might be to come in what's already happening. So far we've had only small skirmishes in what might be the looming trade war, but the effects don't seem trivial to soybean farmers already facing sharp price cuts and steel users already facing much higher costs. If the trade war happens, expect to see many, many more stories like this.

O.K., there's no certainty that any of this will happen. In fact, I still find it hard to believe that we're really going to go down this path. But I also don't have any plausible stories about what's going to make Trump stop, or induce other big players to give in to his demands.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Sunday, June 17, 2018

Sam Webb: Loose ends in dangerous times

Loose ends in dangerous times

1. The old global order dominated by US imperial power with its many contradictions and inequalities is cracking along many seams. But what is much less evident is what will replace it. I would like to be optimistic, but given the weaknesses of the left and progressive movements in the US and elsewhere on the one hand and the momentum and strength of the right on the other, It is hard to be sanguine about the future. In fact, one can make an argument that thanks to Trump, Putin, and other rightists who demagogically exploit the contradictions of everyday life and contemporary capitalism for anti-democratic and selfish purposes that a long era of democratic governance (with its obvious — you don't have to remind me — limitations) could well be in the autumn of its life.

All of which, I believe, gives profound importance to this fall's elections. Here in Kingston, NY we have the opportunity to unseat the Republican House incumbent. Years ago this contest for a House seat might have gone unnoticed by me, but not now. And better yet millions across the country are of the same mind.

2. Few things so viscerally demonstrate the utter inhumanity, cruelty, and depravity of Nazi Germany than the scene in the movie Sophie's Choice when the Nazi officer tells Sophie (Meryl Streep) to decide which of her two children will live and which will die. The Trump administration hasn't got to quite to that point, but in ripping children and babies out of the arms of their parents and interning them in makeshift shelters at the border, what it is doing is in the same ballpark.

3. Below is an excerpt from the speech of AFL-CIO leader Richard Trumka earlier this week to the UAW Constitutional Convention,

"As we fight… as we educate our members… as we campaign this summer and fall, we'll spell out our independent worker agenda again and again. We don't work for any political party. We work for workers, because we want more Republicans who will break rank and stand with working people. And while we're at it, we want fewer Democrats who take our money and energy and then forget who got them elected in the first place."

I find this so wrongheaded given the particular circumstances of this election. I suppose for some it might seem like an expression of political independence, but when looked at concretely, when looked at through the lens of the overarching imperative of electing a Democratic majority to the House and Senate this fall in order to preserve democracy and slow down the many sided, unrelenting, and unprecedented, anti-people offensive of Trump and his Republican Congressional quislings, it fails badly to meet the challenge of the present moment.

Much the same could be said about another remark by Trumka in his speech. He asserted:

"The corporate billionaires can't touch our solidarity… . yet when they attack our institutions… when they attack our ability to fight for our members and our communities… when they attack our ability to harness political power for working people… we'll fight back. We will fight back against every attack on working people, and we'll fight hard… we'll fight to win!

I appreciate the militant spirit expressed by Trumka here; it's sure needed. But I find the claim that "the corporate billionaires can't touch our solidarity" a misrepresentation of reality. That fact is that over the past two years Trump, who represents a healthy section of corporate billionaires, has fractured the solidarity of the labor movement as well as working people generally. And the fractures are along racial, gender, nativist, and nationalist lines. To suggest otherwise is of little help to the very members that Trumka represents, not to mention working people and their allies generally.

What would have served his audience better is if Trumka, much like he did in the presidential campaign of 2008, had spoke forthrightly and tactfully to these divisions . They aren't, after all, strangers to the UAW nor the labor movement across the Midwest at this moment. Trump knows this well. And, he will continue to say and do whatever he is necessary to exacerbate them. Such a posture, whose purpose is to peel away a substantial section of white workers to his side, is at the core of his political and reelection strategy to secure a beachhead in the Midwest in particular and country generally.

Hopefully, Trumka will make a course correction. Still time to do it.

4. Pre-trail detention for Paul Manaford, according to Trump and his minions, is cruel and arbitrary, but when it comes to the breakup of families and the lockup of children and babies at the border, that's perfectly ok, even scriptually sanctioned.

5. If the Summit was so good — and it was a step back from a war of words, threats, and nuclear brinksmanship — what was so bad about the Iran agreement?



--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Saturday, June 16, 2018

Bachtell: A new era for building socialism with ‘Chinese characteristics’

A new era for building socialism with 'Chinese characteristics'


A delegation from the CPUSA of Carol Widom and myself visited China May 26-June 3 at the invitation of the Communist Party of China (CPC) and got a glimpse of these changes. We were invited to attend a forum to celebrate the 200th birthday of Karl Marx with 70 communist, socialist, left and revolutionary parties in Shenzhen, an eco-planned city followed by a week touring Beijing, Hefei, Fengyang County and Xiaogang Village, the site of the first rural economic reforms.

The event reflected the feeling by the CPC that a qualitative turning point has been reached in socialist construction and with China playing a new role on the global stage.

The meeting is an example of China and CPC opening wider to the world and expanding and deepening relations with communist and workers parties.

In December the CPC invited some 200 non-communist political parties, many who are governing, to share results and concepts from 19th CPC Congress last October.

Our week-long visit began with an informational session also attended by delegations from sub-Saharan Africa governments and an official from the United Russia governing party.

The informational session was attended by participants from four simultaneous events covering Africa relations, South America relations, 200th anniversary of Marx's birth, and the Belt-Road Initiative.

The schedule was geared to familiarize us with developments in China and CPC policies toward 'building socialism with Chinese characteristics' in a new era, the economic, governance and party reforms, approach to international relations and role of the CPC itself.

 

New Era

The world is entering a "new era" of global relations driven by China's peaceful ascendance and the decline of US and western imperialism. It will affect everything from global economic relations, to global politics and dynamics among communist and workers parties.

The economic and social developments in China in the 40 years since the start of socialist market reforms and opening the country to the global economy under the leadership of Deng Xiaoping are staggering and unprecedented in human history.

China has leapt from an underdeveloped economy to a largely modern economy and infrastructure almost overnight. Within a decade China will be world's largest economy as measured by GDP.

A recent Ipsos survey revealed 90 percent of Chinese were satisfied with the country's path, while only 37 percent of Americans and 11 percent of French said the same.

But the pace of development came at a cost and also brings its own set of problems and challenges. These include subsuming worker rights to overall development, the growth of the capitalist sector with all its risks, contradictions, economic inequalities and the emergence of a billionaire class along with sharpening class struggle, imbalances between urban and rural economies, growing contradiction between increasing needs and ability to address them, not to mention intensifying ideological struggle and the impact on the environment.

Social equality and consciousness tend to trail behind, far behind in some instances.

According to the CPC, China is in the primary stage of socialist construction; it remains a developing country. One could deduce this refers not just to the country's economics and material level of development, but also to its democratic institutions, civil society and political culture.

Nevertheless, China has achieved a standard of living where everyone can live a "moderately prosperous life". By 2050 the goal is to achieve fully modern, democratic, sustainable socialism.

The CPC sees the main contradiction as between imbalanced growth and the growing expectations and needs of the people.

Economic growth is nearly 7% per year. China accounts for 30% of global economic growth. China poured more concrete 2011-2013 than U.S. did in entire 20th century.

Seven hundred million people have been brought out of extreme poverty since the reforms began. This accounts for 70% of poverty reduction worldwide. They will eliminate poverty in the next 3-5 years. Most remaining extreme poverty is in rural and remote areas, and many of these communities will be relocated.

The standard of living is also being raised. Wages, while still low by U.S. standards have risen for factory workers by 64 percent since 2011 and are now on par with workers in Portugal and South Africa. Workplace safety has improved.

The scale of mega projects is hard to comprehend: knitting together a mega metropolitan area of 130 million encompassing Beijing and two others cities, water diversion from the south to the north, tunnel projects under the ocean, etc.

The 19th CPC Congress projected a new round of openness and economic, social and governance reforms that extend decades into the future. As Xi Jinping said, "The door to the world will open wider and wider."

The CPC projected shifting the economic model from one which is export driven and based on the import of foreign capital and technology to  a "made in China by 2025" model. The goal is radically raising productivity, which is approximately one-third the U.S. economy.

This will be achieved by placing a great emphasis on innovation, science, technology,  artificial intelligence (AI), big data along with modernization of all aspects of governance, business, finance, services, etc. A world class university system is being developed to attract world class scientific talent.

The economy is roughly 60 percent controlled by publicly owned enterprises and publicly controlled enterprises with minority private investment. The government also directs short and long term strategic social investment.

The state asserts absolute control over armaments, power generation and distribution, oil and petrochemicals, telecommunications, coal, aviation and shipping industries.

Ecological civilization

Since the 18th CPC Congress China has been committed to a sustainable path and building an "ecological civilization" as a national strategy.

This comes in response to the ravages of development which were plain to see and a widespread environmental movement and consciousness that arose among the people. The CPC policy promotes harmony of society and nature and overcoming any contradiction between development and sustainability.

The CPC initiated a "war on pollution" just like the "war on poverty". It is a shift from quantity to quality in production, prioritizing environmental protection, and becoming a global leader in the fight against the climate crisis.

China is doubling the previous target for solar power production by 2020 and is the largest producer of solar panels in the world. Plans were halted to build 150 coal fired plants, and installation of desulfurization and denitration filters on the remaining plants is nearly complete; China sells more electric vehicles than Europe and US combined and passed laws to create a circular economy (reuse, recycling and remanufacturing).

A 35,000 kilometer high-speed train network is half complete. This is more than the rest of world combined and will allow people to commute longer distances. The second generation of high-speed trains are completely designed and built in China.

The country is constructing 6 mega windfarms and carrying out the largest reforestation project in the world. A few years ago, Beijing was plagued with regular sandstorms originating in Inner Mongolia. The sandstorms have largely been contained by planting a Great Green Wall.

We saw other examples of an eco-civilization taking shape. Cities are full of greenery and on our bus ride to Xiaogang Village the 50-mile highway was lined with a band of trees 75 feet wide on both sides.

However, enormous challenges remain. China still produces more CO2 than any other country and its developmental goals will keep it committed to coal fired plants. In addition, plastic is ubiquitous and the source of the plastic waste stream include four Chinese Rivers among the top ten emptying into the Pacific Ocean. (although as of 2018 China will no longer import plastic waste from US and EU).

 

International relations

China's economic reforms are also dependent on "opening wider and wider" to the global economy, ensuring a stable global trade environment and peace.

The peaceful rise of China and decline of US imperialism, the emergence of a multi-polar world, deepening and expanding globalization of production and multilateral trade pacts, and the mass communications and technological revolutions are shaping the emergence of a new global dynamic.

The essence of the opening policy is a recognition that no country can develop its economy in isolation and must engage in the globalized economy dominated for the time being by the U.S. and other imperialist powers. China realizes its state owned companies and private corporations must play by these rules and be competitive in the global market.

China is operating by a concept of international relations referred to as "Building a community for a shared future." It involves "two guidelines": build a more just and reasonable new world order and jointly maintain international security.

These are international relations of a new type based on mutual respect regardless of social system, fairness and justice, working out problems peacefully and win-win economic cooperation.

It also involves a new model of relationships between major countries, disputing the prevailing international order, and reforming global governance systems established during post WWII such as the UN Security Council, IMF and World Bank, etc.

It is based on the idea no country can solve problems of development, climate change, peace, poverty, disease, resource allocation, etc. on their own: it takes cooperation.

China will play a bigger role in all international forums, e.g., the Paris Climate Agreement.

China has been building alternative international networks and relationships since the fall of the USSR including the Shanghai Cooperative Organization (SCO), the association of five major emerging economies known as BRICS (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa) and alternative financial institutions to facilitate trade and development including the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank.

From keeping a low profile to becoming assertive and aspirational, China's foreign policy will engage and increasingly impact the dominant pattern of capitalist globalization relations.

One mammoth developmental project is the Belt-Road Initiative (BRI) – $1 trillion investment in road, rail, and maritime ports, energy pipelines, power grids, refineries, connecting 65 countries with trade and cultural exchange. Once complete, the BRI could boost global trade by an estimated 12%.

The BRI is geared to facilitating trade and infrastructure development of countries involved while securing raw materials and resources China needs for its own development, theoretically a win-win.

The opening policy is also having an impact on developments on the Korean peninsula, drawing North Korea into the global economic and governance system.

U.S. ruling circles are divided on foreign policy and trade. Trump's economic protectionism and nationalism is threatening to disrupt the global trading system. China is concerned whether economic nationalism characterizes only the Trump administration or is a fundamental shift by U.S. ruling circles.

The rise of protectionism effects China's drive for openness and reform. These policies depend on deeper connection to the global trading system and creating a more fair and well balanced system.

Trump has targeted China and Russia as strategic rivals. Tariffs and other demands are meant to blunt China's rise by gutting state investment and guidance of the economy, support for high tech and basic scientific sector, and demanding that its finance sector open for foreign investment.

Democracy and governance reform

The CPC is projecting a reform of governance to fit the new era. Emphasis is being placed on establishing a rule of law society, which along with economic reforms, comprise "two wings of bird."

A rule of law society means enforcing the constitution, developing judiciary and legal rights, regulatory bodies, streamlining governmental agencies, environmental and consumer protections, etc. This will take some time to develop and entails cultivating a grassroots democratic culture and vibrant civil society.

Among the biggest problems are the growth of wealth inequality and emergence of a billionaire class which is larger than that in the U.S. One study indicated the National People's Congress had elected delegates with a net worth of $500 billion. The billionaire class is the source of much of the corruption in the society and party and has been expatriating billions of dollars of wealth and investing overseas.

Although an independent media has emerged since Deng Xiaoping, Reporters without Borders ranks press freedom very low. There is a widespread domestic social media, but Facebook, Twitter, YouTube are banned.

The free flow of information in a world of cyber warfare and the battle of ideas are challenges facing every country. But Chinese citizens are finding ways around the bans which means censorship is largely ineffective and will only garner resentment.

 

Women are guaranteed equal rights under the constitution but winning that in reality is far more difficult. Over 80% of women are in the workforce but vestiges of patriarchal society remain including sexual harassment, property rights and unwanted daughters.

The presence of women in CPC leadership and among elected officials is scarce.

Changes are afoot including with a new anti-sexual harassment law and anecdotally we learned over 50% of a geo-physicist class were women.

Gay and lesbian rights also lag far behind. We were told attitudes toward gays and lesbians are like the U.S. military "Don't ask, don't tell" policy. But things are changing among China's younger generation who are totally accepting of different sexual orientations and identities.

We didn't learn anything on the status of national minorities. Affirmative action type development projects are seen as a priority as is respect for cultural traditions. From reports some nationalists and religious extremists are taking advantage of the situation to foment separatist movements. But breaking up China's territory won't be tolerated.

The CPC freely admits there are imperfections in democracy. Take into consideration 2000 years of imperial rule ended in 1912 with the Xinhai Revolution followed by civil war, Japanese occupation and WWII; the revolutionary war for independence resulted in the founding of the People's Republic in 1949 only to be followed by the turmoil of the "Great Leap Forward" and "Cultural Revolution."

China didn't pass through bourgeois democratic republic phase. During its history, a single party emerged as leader. Authoritarian tendencies carried over from the revolutionary war for independence and establishment of socialist republic.

Creating democratic institutions didn't really begin until the reforms of 1978. China's system of elections is hierarchical – each legislative body is drawn from the legislative bodies below. It's system of participatory and consultssative democracy is unique.  National, state and local direct elections are the goal. China is an evolving new democracy.

 

The CPC

The CPC is a deeply revolutionary party, creatively applying Marxism to the Chinese reality. Their approach is pragmatic, fact based, self-critical, and self-reforming.

Far from building a capitalist economy, the CPC is charting a path in the context of China's realities, guiding the country to achieve a modern socialist society under extraordinary difficult conditions and not without many problems, mistakes and shortcomings, one with "Chinese characteristics."

The CPC is forging a path through uncharted territory.

The CPC is leading a country of 1.4 billion people through mind boggling changes. Their experience has a lot of relevance for developing countries and it gives confidence that it is possible to eliminate poverty and adopt a sustainable path of development in a relatively short span of time.

Enormous changes are taking place almost overnight. The CPC believes it is not possible to navigate these changes without a strong, united Party, politically, theoretically and organizationally.

The 19th CPC Congress called for elevating and strengthening the role of the 86 million member party; to strengthen leadership, functioning, intra-party democracy, connection to people, and theoretical development.  As Xi said, "The CPC must change with the times."

Corruption is one of the main challenges undermining authority of the Party. The CPC has taken steps to eliminate extravagant banquets and restore accountability.

Over 30,000 cadres have been dropped from membership including political bureau and provincial leaders. Overall, one million officials have been punished for corruption since 2013.

They are applying Marxism to Chinese reality, insisting each party must adopt its own path, and there are no universal models. Even when one comrade from a fraternal party suggested the 21st century would be the century of Eurasia, the ID CPC leader said it would be "the century of the world's people".

The CPC wants to elevate dialog and sharing because "each party is captive of its experience."

The CPC's opening will have a good effect on communist, socialist and revolutionary parties around the world. They are injecting refreshing, new concepts based on a unique experience. They insist they are not trying to impose their model, there is no new "center", that equality between parties and countries big or small must be the norm.

But by their mere size and accomplishments they will have huge influence.

The image of Chinese socialism, positive and negative, will have a big impact on how people in the U.S. view socialism. China's model is not ours and the complexity of development makes it hard to explain to the American people. We can discuss the positive achievements but must find ways to explain China's unique history, problems, and shortcomings in a partisan way without arrogance on our part.

And most of all we must continue to develop our own vision of a democratic, demilitarized, sustainable socialism and the democratic path we project to get there.


--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Noah Smith: Unions Did Great Things for the working class


Unions Did Great Things for the Working Class

Strengthening them could blunt inequality and wage stagnation.


Politically and economically, unions are sort of an odd duck. They aren't part of the apparatus of the state, yet they depend crucially on state protections in order to wield their power. They're stakeholders in corporations, but often have adversarial relationships with management. Historically, unions are a big reason that the working class won many of the protections and rights it now enjoys, but they often leave the working class fragmented and divided -- between different companies, between union and non-union workers, and even between different ethnic groups.

Economists, too, have long puzzled about how to think about unions. They don't fit easily into the standard paradigm of modern economic theory in which atomistic individuals and companies abide by rules overseen by an all-powerful government. Some economists see unions as a cartel, protecting insiders at the expense of outsiders. According to this theory, unions raise wages but also drive up unemployment. This is the interpretation of unions taught in many introductory courses and textbooks.

If this were really what unions did, it might be worth it to simply let them slip into oblivion, as private-sector unions have been doing in the U.S.:

It's Been a While Since the Union Made Us Strong

Share of workforce belonging to unions in the private sector

Source: Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson via Unionstat.com

But there are many reasons to think that this theory of unions isn't right -- or, at least, is woefully incomplete.

First, even back in the 1970s, some economists realized that unions do a lot more than just push up wages. In a 1979 paper entitled "The Two Faces of Unionism," economists Richard Freeman and James Medoff argued that "by providing workers with a voice both at the workplace and in the political arena, unions can and do affect positively the functioning of the economic and social systems."

Freeman and Medoff cite data showing that unions reduced turnover, which lowers costs associated with constantly finding and training new workers. They also show that unions engaged in political activity that benefitted the working class more broadly, rather than just union members. And they showed that contrary to popular belief, unions actually decreased racial wage disparities. Finally, Freeman and Medoff argue that by defining standard wage rates within industries, unions actually reduced wage inequality overall, despite the cartel-like effect emphasized in econ textbooks.

But the world didn't listen to Freeman and Medoff, and private-sectors unions declined into near-insignificance. Now, four decades later, economists are again starting to suspect that unions were a better deal than the textbooks made them out to be. A recent paper by economists Henry Farber, Daniel Herbst, Ilyana Kuziemko and Suresh Naidu concludes that unions were an important force reducing inequality in the U.S.
QuicktakeIncomeInequality

Since past data tends to be patchy, Farber et al. combine a huge number of different data sources to get a detailed picture of unionization rates going all the way back to 1936, the year after Congress passed a law letting private-sector employees form unions. The authors find that as unionization rises, inequality tends to fall, and vice versa. Nor is this effect driven by greater skills and education on the part of union workers; during the era from 1940 through 1970, when unionization rose and inequality fell, union workers tended to be less educated than others. In other words, unions lifted the workers at the bottom of the distribution. Black workers, and other nonwhite workers, tended to benefit the most from the union boost.

Now, however, private-sector unions are mostly a faded memory and their power to raise wages has waned -- Farber et al. find that although there's still a union wage premium, it's now much more due to the fact that higher-skilled workers tended to be the ones who stayed unionized. A 2004 paper by economists John DiNardo and David Lee found that by 1984-1999, unions had lost much of their ability to force wages higher.

Given the contrast between the golden age of 1940-1970 and the current age of spiraling inequality, wouldn't it make sense to bring unions back? Perhaps. The key question is why private-sector unions mostly died out. Policy changes -- right-to-work laws, and the appointment of anti-union regulators, probably played a key role in reducing unionization. But globalization may have also played a big part. Competition from companies in countries like Germany -- where unions often bargain to hold down wages in order to increase their companies' competitiveness -- might have made the old American model of unionization unsustainable. Now, with even stiffer competition from China, the challenge of re-unionizing the U.S. might be an insurmountable one.

But it might be worth it to try. Other than massive government redistribution of income and wealth, there's really no other obvious way to address the country's rising inequality. Also, there's the chance that unions might be an effective remedy for the problem of increasing corporate market power -- evidence suggests that when unionization rates are high, industry concentration is less effective at suppressing wages. Repealing right-to-work laws and appointing more pro-union regulators could be just the medicine the economy needs.

So supporters of free markets should rethink their antipathy to unions. As socialism gains supportamong the young, both economists and free-market thinkers should consider the possibility that unions -- that odd hybrid of free-market bargaining and government intervention -- were the vaccine that allowed the U.S. and other rich nations to largely escape the disasters of communism in the 20th century.

It looks like it's time for a booster shot.



--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.