Friday, December 8, 2017

Chart of the Week: Sharing the Wealth: Inequality and Who Owns What [feedly]

Chart of the Week: Sharing the Wealth: Inequality and Who Owns What
https://blogs.imf.org/2017/12/07/chart-of-the-week-sharing-the-wealth-inequality-and-who-owns-what/

 -- via my feedly newsf

By IMFBlog

December 7, 2017

Luxury yachts in Monaco: The surge in top incomes, combined with high savings, has resulted in growing wealth inequality (photo: Eric Gaillard/Newscom).

Income inequality among people around the world has been declining in recent decades. But the news is not all good. Inequality within many countries has increased, particularly in advanced economies.

In addition to income inequality, wealth inequality—what you have accumulated, as opposed to what you earn—is closely related, and reflects differences in savings, inheritances, and bequests.

In our Chart of the Week from the October Fiscal Monitor, we zoom in on inequality of wealth—the distribution of wealth across households or individuals at a given time. 

Wealth is more unequally distributed than income. As the chart shows for the countries listed, all part of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, the average share of wealth held by the top 10 percent of households is 50 percent, which by far exceeds the average share of income, 24 percent, held by the top 10 percent. In the United States, the top 1 percent holds nearly 40 percent of total net wealth. Financial assets, such as equities, life insurance, and pensions, to name a few, make up a large share of household wealth at the very top. 

The latest Fiscal Monitor shows that wealth inequality has risen considerably in recent decades. The surge in top incomes, combined with high savings, has resulted in growing wealth inequality.

Fiscal policy is a powerful tool for governments to address high and rising income and wealth inequality. The Fiscal Monitor shows that equity and efficiency can and must go hand-in-hand. Policymakers need to consider both taxes and transfers, and have many policies from which to choose.  The Fiscal Monitor focuses on three policy debates: progressive taxation, universal basic income (UBI), and public spending on education and health.eed

Net Neutrality Likely to Accelerate the Trend in Media Consolidation [feedly]

Net Neutrality Likely to Accelerate the Trend in Media Consolidation
http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2017/12/net-neutrality-likely-to-accelerate-the-trend-in-media-consolidation.html

The conclusion of a post by Harold Feld at ProMarket:

Will Repeal of Net Neutrality Accelerate the Trend in Media Consolidation? The History of Cable Suggests "Yes," by Harold Feld, ProMarket: ...Based on the history of both the cable industry and the broadband industry (which is, after all, almost entirely derived from the cable industry), we should expect repeal of the net neutrality to rules to accelerate the trend toward vertical and horizontal consolidation. This is particularly true in light of the public statements of chairman Pai and other Republican commissioners indicating they believe that consolidation can offer benefits to consumers and that the dangers of anticompetitive behavior are exaggerated. This is not only true about net neutrality, but generally. Although chairman for less than a year, Pai has already announced that the FCC will simply defer to the Department of Justice on antitrust and to the Federal Trade Commission on consumer protection, and has either repealed or begun the process of repealing the FCC's longstanding limits on vertical and horizontal media ownership.
Additionally, although Pai and the other Republican commissioners repeatedly refer to state consumer protection laws as providing an additional layer of protection, the draft order repealing net neutrality also contains sweeping language preempting the states from any laws "inconsistent" with the "deregulatory policy" the FCC will adopt on December 14. Charter Communication (which now owns Time Warner Cable) has already rushed to use this language to file a motion to dismiss a lawsuit by the New York state attorney general relating to Time Warner Cable's 2014 conduct denying New York subscribers access to Netflix. Whether or not this particular motion to dismiss succeeds, we can expect broadband provider to use the broad preemption language in the net neutrality repeal order to block precisely the kind of state consumer protection statutes chairman Pai claims will make FCC oversight unnecessary.
In short, the net neutrality repeal order does for broadband exactly what the 1984 Cable Act did for cable—create an environment with virtually no effective restraint on the ability of providers to favor their own content and discriminate against rivals. We should therefore expect the same result: rapid horizontal and vertical consolidation. While chairman Pai and other supporters of the repeal order dismiss these concerns, they offer no plausible explanation for why this round of deregulation should produce different results beyond an airy wave that all that consolidation is ancient history and how could that possibly happen again?
As we all know, those who refuse to learn from history are doomed to repeat it.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Paul Krugman: Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits [feedly]

Paul Krugman: Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits
http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2017/12/paul-krugman-republicans-are-coming-for-your-benefits.html

offsetting those deficits will require going after the true big-ticket programs, namely Medicare and Social Security":

Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits, by Paul Krugman, NY Times: ...During the Senate debate over the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, Senator Orrin Hatch was challenged over support for the Children's Health Insurance Program, which covers nine million U.S. children — but whose funding lapsed two months ago... Hatch ... insisted that "the reason CHIP's having trouble is because we don't have money anymore" — just before voting for a trillion-and-a-half-dollar tax cut that will deliver the bulk of its benefits to the richest few percent....
He then went on to say, "I have a rough time wanting to spend billions and billions and trillions of dollars to help people who won't help themselves, won't lift a finger and expect the federal government to do everything."
So who, exactly, was he talking about...?
Was he talking about food stamps, most of whose beneficiaries are children, elderly or disabled? ... Was he talking about the earned-income tax credit, which rewards only those who work? Was he talking about Medicaid, which again mainly benefits children, the elderly and the disabled, plus people who work hard but whose jobs don't provide health benefits?
We can go on down the list. The simple fact is that big spending on people who "won't lift a finger" doesn't actually happen in America — only in Hatch's meanspirited imagination.
Now, to be fair..., some people ... get lots of money they didn't lift a finger to earn — namely, inheritors of large estates. ...Republican legislation would give these people ... billions and billions of dollars... How can this be justified if it's supposedly hard to find money for children's health care?
Well, Senator Chuck Grassley explained it all last week: "I think not having the estate tax recognizes the people that are investing, as opposed to those that are just spending every darn penny they have, whether it's on booze or women or movies." ...
The important thing to realize, however, is that the hypocrisy and contempt for the public we've seen ... is just the beginning..., budget deficits are going to soar... And offsetting those deficits will require going after the true big-ticket programs, namely Medicare and Social Security.
Oh, they'll find euphemisms to describe what they're doing, talking solemnly about the need for "entitlement reform" as an act of fiscal responsibility — while their huge budget-busting tax cut for the rich gets shoved down the memory hole. But whatever words they use to cloak the reality of the situation, Republicans have given their donors what they wanted — and now they're coming for your benefits.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

The distribution of TCJA cuts, as well as the burden of financing them, by income group and race [feedly]

The distribution of TCJA cuts, as well as the burden of financing them, by income group and race
http://www.epi.org/blog/distribution-tax-cuts-and-jobs-act-by-income-race/

The House and Senate both passed versions of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) in recent weeks. Both versions of the bill, which must now be reconciled and voted on again, are made up mostly of large, hugely regressive tax cuts that give disproportionate benefits to big corporations and the wealthiest Americans. While the regressivity of these bills by income class has been well-documented by now, we've been asked by a number of people about the likely distribution of tax cuts called for by the TCJA across racial groups. A fully fleshed-out and precise estimate of this racial distribution would take lots of time and effort to calculate, but a decent rough estimate can be made pretty quickly if we're willing to use some plausible proxy data.

However, it is also crucially important to note that congressional Republicans have not just passed versions of the TCJA in recent weeks, they have also passed a budget resolution calling for steep cuts to key programs, in large part because they want this money to finance their tax cuts. Assessing the impact of tax cuts while ignoring likely spending cuts would lead to a radical underestimate of the effect of coming fiscal policy changes on typical Americans' livelihoods. Given this, we also examine the likely distribution of the burden of financing the TCJA with spending cuts by income class and race.

The Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center (TPC) has provided estimates of what share of the tax cuts would go to different income groups. The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) provides data on the share of households in each of various income groupings that are headed by white, African American, or Hispanic householders. The SCF is uniquely useful here because it has clear income percentile rankings all the way up to the top 1 percent. Merging the TPC and SCF data in this way is not a pure apples-to-apples comparison. The TPC data is arranged by "tax units" while the SCF data is arranged by households (while the SCF calls their unit of analysis "families", it is much closer to the "household" definition used by surveys like the Census). A tax unit can contain more than one household. But, all this said, there still should be substantial overlap between the two data measures, and the TPC data on tax units should provide a useful overview of the distribution of tax cuts across households.

The first row of Table 1 below shows the current distribution of income by income percentile class. The next four rows show the share of each income percentile class that is white, African American, Hispanic and "other" (in the coding of the SCF). Unsurprisingly, white families constitute the majority of every income percentile group. But it is striking (if not surprising) that their share is lowest in the bottom two-fifths of the income distribution and highest in the top 1 percent. Both African American and Hispanic shares are highest in the bottom two fifths and fall monotonically as one moves higher in income percentile rankings. The upshot of this for the distribution of policy changes is crystal-clear: regressive policy changes are likely to inflict the most damage (or provide the least benefit) to non-white families.

Table 1

The sixth and seventh rows of Table 1 shows the distribution of the TCJA tax cuts by income percentile class, for both the House and Senate versions of the bill. As has been pointed out before, the benefits of both versions of this tax cut are astoundingly regressive, with the overall top 1 percent claiming 47.6 and 62.6 percent of total benefits in the House and Senate versions respectively, while the bottom 40 percent of tax units claim less than 2 percent of the total benefits of the House bill and actually see tax increases from the Senate bill.

But as many analysts have noted, examining only the direct effect of tax cuts without accounting for how these cuts will be financed in the long-run is likely to lead to wildly misleading conclusions about their effects. Given this, Table 1 also shows the distributional impact by income percentile class of two illustrative ways that the tax cut could be financed.

The first financing method examined is simply be a lump-sum tax increase on tax units – every tax unit paying an identical dollar sum large enough to neutralize the economy-wide, overall cost of the TCJA (this lump-sum financing was examined by TPC). It could be objected that this is quite unrealistic: lump-sum taxes don't exist in the real world and won't be used to finance the tax cut. This is fair enough – but the entire economic argument that the TCJA will lead to economic growth implicitly presumes that the taxes cut in the framework will be offset by financing that has no behavioral effect at all – which can essentially only occur with lump-sum tax increases. The distribution of the burden of financing the TCJA with a lump-sum increase is predictably regressive. The bottom two-fifths would bear 50.1 percent of the burden while the top 1 percent would face just 0.7 percent.1

Finally, Table shows the distributional impact by income group of financing the TCJA tax cuts with across-the-board cuts in all federal spending except Social Security and defense. This is a rough but fair characterization of the budget resolution passed last month by the Senate and House – very large cuts to all spending except these programs. In fact, the budget resolution, if anything, directed cuts more regressively than an across-the-board cut in non-defense, non-Social Security spending might indicate. For example, cuts to Medicaid fall much more heavily on the bottom of the income distribution than do cuts to Medicare. But Medicare remains a larger overall expenditure, yet the budget resolution directed larger cuts to Medicaid than Medicare.

Yet even with an assumption that actually lightens the likely regressivity of the Congressional budget resolution, this method of financing the TJCA would still result in a steeply regressive burden, with the bottom two-fifths bearing 38.7 percent of the cut (as opposed to their income share of just 13.1 percent) just while the top 1 percent faces just 4.4 percent (relative to their 15.3 percent income share).2

The information in this table allows us to show the total share of income, tax cuts and the burden of financing them that is faced by families by income percentile and race. Table 2shows the share of total income, the share of tax cuts and the share of the burden of financing these tax cuts facing white, African American and Hispanic families in each income percentile class. The first block of rows simply shows the shares of total income accounted for by race and income percentile. So, for example, white families in the bottom fifth of the income distribution account for 2.6 percent of total income, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth account for 1.1 and 0.5 percent of total income, respectively. White families in the top 1 percent account for 14.1 percent of total income, while African American and Hispanic families in the top 1 percent account for 0.2 and 0.3 percent of total income (shares that are low because so few African American and Hispanic families are in the overall top 1 percent).

Table 2

The next two blocks show the shares of the TCJA tax cuts by race and income percentile, for both the House and Senate versions. For the House bill, the first row in this block of columns, for example, shows that 0.2 percent of the benefits of the House TCJA go to white families in the bottom fifth of the income distribution, 0.1 percent of the benefits go to African Americans in the bottom fifth, and less than 0.005 percent goes to Hispanic families in the bottom fifth.

Moving to the top 1 percent row, this shows that 44.1 percent of the benefits of the House TCJA go to white families in the top 1 percent, 0.6 percent go to African American families in the top 1 percent, and 1.0 percent go to Hispanic families in the top 1 percent. The final row sums these to show total benefits of the tax cut by race, but it is important to realize that (for example), while 90.3 percent of the total benefits go to white families, this is driven overwhelmingly by just the top 1 percent.

For the Senate bill, the bottom 40 percent of all races see tax increases from the TCJA. Moving to the top 1 percent row, 58.0 percent of the benefits of the Senate TCJA go to white families in the top 1 percent, 0.8 percent go to African American families in the top 1 percent, and 1.3 percent go to Hispanic families in the top 1 percent. The final row sums these to show total benefits of the tax cut by race, but it is important to realize that (for example), while 90.1 percent of the total benefits go to white families, this is driven overwhelmingly by just the top 1 percent.

The next group of rows shows the distribution of the burden of financing these tax cuts if done with lump-sum taxes, by both income percentile class and race. Again, the first row can be read to show that white families in the bottom fifth would bear 16.5 percent of the total burden of financing tax cuts with lump-sum increases, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth would bear 6.7 and 3.5 percent, respectively. White families in the top 1 percent would bear just 0.6 percent of the total cost of financing tax cuts with lump-sum tax increases, while African American and Hispanic families would bear less than 0.05 percent of the burden. These numbers on lump-sum tax burden do not perfectly reflect population shares because there are more tax units in the lower fifths of the population than in higher fifths. This, combined with higher African American and Hispanic shares in these lower fifths, means that a lump-sum tax levied on tax units will hit them disproportionately.

Finally, the fourth set of bars shows the distribution of the burden of financing these tax cuts if it was done with an across-the-board cutback in government spending, except for defense and Social Security. Again, despite making an assumption that softens how regressive the spending cut in the Congressional budget resolution would be, the burden still falls heavily on non-white families because of the overall regressivity. White families in the bottom fifth would bear 10.3 percent of the burden, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth would bear 4.2 and 2.2 percent. White families in the top 1 percent would bear just 4 percent of the burden, while African American and Hispanic families in the top 1 percent would both bear 0.1 percent of the burden.

The regressive distribution of both benefits from the TCJA and the burden of financing them is near-entirely a function of income ranking. But we know that the historical legacy of racism and discrimination has led to a non-random distribution of racial groups across the income distribution, with the result that white families overall would see larger benefits from tax cuts and would bear lighter burdens from financing them, while non-white families see smaller gains but larger burdens from the TCJA. To be clear, the benefits even across white families are extraordinarily concentrated at the top – a third of white families will see outright tax increases from the Senate bill, for example. But we shouldn't be blind to disproportionate racial costs and benefits from fiscal policies.

1. Calculating the burden of financing tax cuts with lump-sum tax increases is done by simply taking Tax Policy Center (TPC) estimates of the share of total tax units in each income percentile class. The lower fifths of the income distribution tend to have more tax units (i.e. relatively more single filers), so, a lump-sum tax levied on tax units would fall more heavily on lower-income tax units.

2. Calculating the burden of financing tax cuts with across-the-board cuts in government spending except Social Security and Defense is done by using data from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO). The CBO provides data that allows estimates on the distribution of total transfer payments except for Social Security by income percentile class. CBO also provides guidance on how to distributionally allocate the benefit of federal government consumption and investment spending (or non-transfer spending). The CBO suggest two methods – allocating the benefit of this as a lump-sum across the population, or allocating benefits proportional to income. We allocate non-transfer spending by taking a simple average of these two approaches. We then weight the transfer and non-transfer cuts by current shares of transfers and non-transfer spending in federal spending. In 2016, transfers to persons besides Social Security were roughly half of all non-defense federal spending.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

What to Watch on Jobs Day: Labor market should continue to improve, with or without pending tax cuts [feedly]

What to Watch on Jobs Day: Labor market should continue to improve, with or without pending tax cuts
http://www.epi.org/blog/what-to-watch-on-jobs-day-labor-market-should-continue-to-improve-with-or-without-pending-tax-cuts/

Tomorrow, the BLS will release the latest numbers on job creation and the labor market. Today, I'm going to take step back and provide some context for what we've seen so far this year, as we approach the 10th anniversary of the beginning of the Great Recession. I'm also going to provide some perspective on the tax bill wending its way through Congress, in light of steady progress in the labor market over the last several years. The bottom line is that (1) contrary to recent economic commentary surrounding the proposed tax cuts in Congress, it is not clear that we have reached genuine full employment yet and significant slack may still remain in the labor market , but (2) if we continue to see solid payroll employment growth in the months to come, we should expect to see continued strong progress in labor force participation, particularly among prime-age workers, and in wage growth—even in the absence of any fiscal stimulus from tax cuts. Any claims that these tax cuts, if they pass, will lead to significant improvement in the labor market or in wages need to be viewed in the context of an already steadily improving economy.

In January 2017, we released our autopilot economy tracker, as a way to set down key benchmarks for the U.S. economy. Think of it as providing a gauge of whether changes to policy are leaving any discernible mark on the economy's trajectory. We look at where several economic indicators were headed before the year started, and where they would be if those trends simply continued. Take, for example, the prime-age employment to population ratio (EPOP). In the figure below, you can see clearly the progress that has been made over the last several years, and the continuation of that trend through this year with no discernible uptick in the pace of recovery. Steady improvements in the prime-age EPOP since January have tracked our predictions of an economy on auto-pilot fairly well, and we should expect this trend to continue into next year.

EPOP 2015-2019
EPOP 1995-2019

The same goes for other indicators. Currently, the unemployment rate is beating expectations while nominal wage growth remains weaker than expected. However, as the economy continues to solidly add jobs, more would-be workers will be pulled back into the labor force. As that pool of potential workers who are currently jobless shrinks away, workers will have more bargaining power, which will translate into stronger wage growth. In turn, employers will begin investing more in labor-saving equipment and technology and we should see stronger productivity growth—which clears out even more room for wages to grow. This is the virtuous cycle we would like to see happen as the economy continues moving toward full employment, and there are clear signs that this process is beginning.

This analysis highlights the crucial importance of "high-pressure" labor markets for wage growth. An alternative visions says that it's the tax rate faced by corporations that is key to wage growth. The evidence for this tax-centric view of wage growth is weak, as my colleague Josh Bivens explains. The crux of his argument is that (1) productivity and wage growth have been significantly greater in periods with higher corporate tax rates, (2) there is no robust relationship between post-tax profit rates and productivity-enhancing investments, and (3) productivity growth is only a necessary, not sufficient, condition for wage growth (as we've seen in the last four decades when typical compensation has growth significantly slower than the rate of productivity growth). Furthermore, corporate tax cuts do nothing in terms of giving American workers more leverage and bargaining power to acquire a significant share of those higher profits in the form of wages. In short, the push to cut corporate tax rates is a distraction from what can boost wages quickly: a spell of genuine full employment.

This spell of genuine full employment might not be that far away, so, it's important that we recognize that stronger wage growth is on the horizon anyhow, and if these regressive tax cuts are passed, we cannot attribute that stronger wage growth and improvements in the labor market in general to said tax cuts.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Monday, December 4, 2017

Yet more on the terrible tax plan…



----
Yet more on the terrible tax plan… // Jared Bernstein | On the Economy
http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/yet-more-on-the-terrible-tax-plan/

Similar pieces wherein I'm trying to work out some of the longer term implications of what's happening with tax policy, the debt, and the forthcoming attack on spending programs that, you know, actually help some people.

Over at WaPo and TAP.

I've not forgotten that there's much else going on. I've got forthcoming pieces on the attack on financial market regulation, which, unless you're following this, goes deeper than you thought, and current economic conditions as a baseline against which to evaluate a bunch of silly claims that will soon be made about the impact of the tax plan on growth.


----

Read in my feedly.com

Enlighten Radio Podcasts:The Moose Turd Cafe -- KellyAnne Cocaine Opioid Extermination Camp Plan

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Enlighten Radio Podcasts
Post: The Moose Turd Cafe -- KellyAnne Cocaine Opioid Extermination Camp Plan
Link: http://podcasts.enlightenradio.org/2017/12/the-moose-turd-cafe-kellyanne-cocaine.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/