Friday, August 25, 2017

Media's Biased Reporting on China Serves Only the Rich and Powerful [feedly]

Media's Biased Reporting on China Serves Only the Rich and Powerful
http://cepr.net/publications/op-eds-columns/media-s-biased-reporting-on-china-serves-only-the-rich-and-powerful

Media's Biased Reporting on China Serves Only the Rich and Powerful

Dean Baker
The Hill, August 20, 2017

See article on original site

This month, a leading newspaper ran a column bashing China by two former U.S. intelligence officials. The piece claimed that the United States loses $600 billion a year due to "intellectual property theft" and that "China accounts for most of that loss."

This was striking for two reasons. First, the number is obviously absurd. Reputable news outlets usually make writers provide some backup for the numbers they use. That doesn't seem to have been the case here. Second, if the number were plausible, the implications for policy on intellectual property and inequality would be enormous.

Starting with the absurdity of the $600 billion figure, this is more than 25 percent of the value of all U.S. exports. It's more than one-third of all after-tax corporate profits in America. Does anyone really want to argue that corporate profits in the U.S. would be one third higher if companies were paid for intellectual property that was stolen from them?

While the piece gave no source, industry groups have produced such outlandish numbers in the past by assuming that all unauthorized versions of their product would sell at the retail price in the United States. This means that if the retail price of Windows and the Microsoft Office Suite is $100, and a hundred million unauthorized copies are in use in China, they would count this as $10 billion.

Or to take another example, the Hepatitis C drug Sovaldi has a list price in the U.S. of $84,000. A high quality generic version is available in India for $300. If a million people use the Indian generic, this would count this as $84 billion of stolen property. Of course, Microsoft and Gilead Sciences (the maker of Sovaldi) would never see anything like this revenue. If the users of the allegedly stolen intellectual property (the rules are not clear) had to pay the retail price in the United States, almost none of them would buy it.

This point should be pretty obvious to anyone with even the most basic understanding of economics, so how does such an absurd number find its way into a major newspaper? It's hard not to see a pretty serious class bias problem. While many major news outlets have run pieces ridiculing efforts to reduce the trade deficit in manufacturing jobs, they are prepared to push nonsense arguments to promote the interests of the pharmaceutical industry, the software industry and the entertainment industry in trade deals.

Needless to say, all the condescending arguments made against the people pushing for more balance in manufacturing trade would apply at least as strongly in the case of their intellectual property claims. Think of how much more money developing countries would have to spend on our cutting edge manufactured products if they didn't have to pay so much money to Microsoft for its software and Pfizer for its drugs?

We also keep hearing about integrated supply chains and how they make things so complicated. Well, if we could get cheaper solar panels from Chinese manufacturers who "steal" intellectual property from companies here (according to their claims), then there will be more jobs in the U.S. for people installing solar panels here. How about some condescending news stories explaining this to the whiners pushing for stronger intellectual property rules who are too dumb to understand the simple economics?

While the double standard at work here is striking, it is worth asking for a moment what it would mean if this absurd $600 billion figure was real. If our companies are losing $600 billion to stolen intellectual property each year, then the total value of patents and copyrights and related protections in the U.S. must be at least three or four times this amount. That would put it in the neighborhood of $1.8 trillion to $2.4 trillion.

This is roughly twice the annual wage income of the bottom 50 percent of workers. It is equal to the full amount of the upward redistribution to the richest one percent over the last four decades. In other words, this is a huge amount of money. If this figure is accurate, then where were all the debates over the steps taken in the last four decades to make patents, copyrights, and related protections longer and stronger?

These protections are supposed to boost growth by providing incentives for innovation and creative work. We know that they increase inequality, since no poor person is collecting royalties or licensing fees. Bill Gates collects a lot of money this way. If we think there is so much money at stake, we should have been debating whether patent and copyright protections were leading to gains in growth that warranted the resulting increase in inequality. We didn't.

Not highlighting the distributional aspects of our policy on intellectual property is an enormous failure of the media even using the real numbers. The failure would be of gargantuan proportions if the numbers the numbers that appeared in this column bashing China were real. The media's neglect in this area serves the interests of the rich and powerful. It is not responsible reporting.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Higher Ed Funding Down in Nearly Every State Over Past Decade [feedly]

Higher Ed Funding Down in Nearly Every State Over Past Decade
https://www.cbpp.org/blog/higher-ed-funding-down-in-nearly-every-state-over-past-decade


A decade since the Great Recession hit, state spending on public colleges and universities remains well below historic levels, despite recent increases, our major new report details.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

New Report Shows Cassidy-Graham Bill Would Deeply Cut Health Coverage Funding for West Virginia [feedly]

New Report Shows Cassidy-Graham Bill Would Deeply Cut Health Coverage Funding for West Virginia
http://www.wvpolicy.org/new-report-shows-cassidy-graham-bill-would-deeply-cut-health-coverage-funding-for-west-virginia/

For Immediate Release
Media Contact: Caitlin Cook304.720.8682

(Charleston, WV) – A new ACA repeal bill would cut West Virginia's federal funding for health coverage by $284 million by 2026, according to a report released today by the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities.

Congressional Republicans' efforts to repeal the Affordable Care Act (ACA) have failed in recent months in large part because a vast majority of Americans oppose taking coverage from millions of people, raising costs for millions more, gutting Medicaid and undermining consumer protections.

This has opened the door to another path: a transparent, bipartisan effort to strengthen our health care system without taking people's coverage away or gutting Medicaid. The public supports this approach and bipartisan Senate hearings slated for September offer a first step forward.
Senators Bill Cassidy and Lindsey Graham are reportedly working with the White House to block this emerging, bipartisan path and instead revive the ACA repeal effort by pushing their own version of a repeal bill, the Cassidy-Graham proposal.
"Despite claims to the contrary, the Cassidy-Graham plan is just another ACA repeal bill and would have the same devastating effects on West Virginia as the previous, failed GOP repeal bills," said Sean O'Leary of the West Virginia Center on Budget and Policy. "Like every other ACA repeal bill, it would take coverage from thousands of West Virginians and tens of millions nationwide."
The plan would eliminate the ACA Medicaid expansion, which covers 170,000 West Virginians. It would also eliminate tax credits that help 25,841 moderate-income West Virginians afford marketplace coverage and subsidies that help low-income West Virginians with out-of-pocket health costs like copays.
A far smaller block grant would replace both Medicaid expansion funding and marketplace subsidies, and the plan would also cap and deeply cut the rest of the Medicaid program just like previous Senate and House repeal bills. And, after 2026, the block grant would disappear entirely leaving West Virginians high and dry.
"The public, experts across the political spectrum, and groups representing patients, hospitals, physicians, seniors, people with disabilities and others have forcefully and repeatedly rejected this misguided approach, said O'Leary. "It's time to focus on bipartisan solutions that strengthen – rather than weaken — our health care system."
The West Virginia Center on Budget and Policy is a public policy research organization that is nonpartisan, nonprofit, and statewide. The Center focuses on how policy decisions affect all West Virginians, especially low- and moderate-income fam

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Simon Wren-Lews: Brexit remains an exercise in deception [feedly]

Simon Wren Lewis makes an interesting observation  at the end of this post. I think the intuition of many -- including on the 'Left' -- is indeed that not only "economic theory" is "just opinion, not science". This is a product of economic issues being the major subject of most politics--the field where all interests are in contention. The same intuition that can't buy "economic science" completely disregards "political science".

One of the unfortunate ideological consequences of this "gulf in economic knowledge" is that the same intuition begins to suspect that the real economy, not just the study of it, is also just  a matter of opinion, subjectivity, and arbitrarily under the direction of whoever is most powerful, or rich. 

Let me put it this way: except in extraordinary historical moments, economic systems choose YOU. You don't choose them. It's not a buffet.

Brexit remains an exercise in deception

Simon Wren-Lewis

http://mainlymacro.blogspot.com/2017/08/brexit-remains-exercise-in-deception.html

talkedlast week about how the Leave campaign involved lies at its centre. Not the occasional exaggerations of the Remain campaign, but claiming things that were the opposite of the truth. Like there will be more money for the NHS, when in fact there will be less. That particular lie probably swung the result, accordingto the man who organised the Leave campaign.

Labour people tell me that public opinion on Brexit will turn once these lies become apparent, and at that point Labour can safely take up the Remain cause. What this overlooks is that the managing of information characterised by the Brexit campaign continues. The Tory tabloids continue to distort the truth, and the Telegraph acts in a very similar fashion. The UK government appears more interested in saying stuff to pleaseits UK audience than actually negotiating with the EU, and its studies of the impactof Brexit remain secret [1].

Meanwhile the opposition give no hint of the costs that Brexit will involve, and by designor conflicted confusion are just a tiny bit less pro-Brexit than the government. The broadcast media, and particularly the BBC, appear hopeless at questioning the facade that both main parties and supporting think tanks have erected. I have never heard a politician pulled up for saying we must retain access to the Single Market: all countries have access to that market! (Thisis the kind of journalism we should be seeing.) Individual MPs are intimidatedinto silence by the power of the Tory tabloids.

When I talk to Leave voters, all they tell me is how the economic 'catastrophe' predicted by Remain did not come to pass, or other Leave nonsense talking points like the exchange rate was overvalued anyway. They are often unaware that falling real wages are the direct result of the Brexit depreciation, and as a result the economy hardly grew in the first half of this year. They, and many people who voted Remain, do not realise that the government's position papers are largelyfantasy and that the EU is in a position to dictate terms. This is not because these voters minds are closed. They just get their information from sources that go along with the government's Brexit fantasy, unless they are fortunate enough to read the Financial Times. No wonder there has been no majorchange in public opinion since the referendum.

Those in the Labour party should realise more than most how the media can present a one-sided reality which many non-political voters accept, until they see for themselves the other side during a general election campaign. The problem with a 'wait and see' attitude to Brexit is that its major economic cost will not become apparent until years after we actually leave the Single Market. Few realise that the original Treasury study, with the central estimate of an average annual cost of £4,300 per household (6.2% of GDP) was not some piece of Remain spin but a perfectly reputable study, which economists at the LSE saidwas "overly cautious". Instead we get nonsense like thisreported by the BBC. [2]

Some time ago I calculated a conservative estimate for the cost of austerity, and it was £4,000 per household. Ironically it was based on OBR estimates that the MSM largely ignored, just as they ignore the OBR's estimates for the short term cost of Brexit. But my austerity cost estimate was a total cost, over all the years of austerity. The Treasury estimate is a cost each year. There is therefore a strong liklihood that Brexit will be far far worse than austerity in terms of lost resources, and unlike austerity there is no way of avoiding these costs once we are outside the Single Market.

For Labour party members and MPs I would put it this way. Imagine winning the next election but having to accept continuing austerity. Winning an election after leaving the Single Market will probably be much worse, and of course the media and voters will blame it all not on Brexit but on Labour's 'far left' policies. Winning an election after Brexit is a poisoned chalice.

[1] Hereis Mike Galsworthy on this and the earlier 'Balance of Competences' reviews that the government kept very quiet about before and during the referendum.

[2] I've talked to people at the BBC, including their economics editor, about why they cannot apply the BBC Trust's recommendationson science coverage to economics. (The Trust's conclusion, in summary, is that in controversial areas the BBC should go with the overwhelming scientific consensus. In other words recognise scientific knowledge, and not treat it as just an opinion.) I think a summary of their response to my question is that economics should not be regarded as a science: there is no economic knowledge, just opinions. What that attitude means in practice is that the public do not hear from the many experts in international trade we have in the UK (and there are many), but instead they hear from Patrick Minford.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

The productivity slowdown is even more puzzling than you think | VOX, CEPR’s Policy Portal

http://voxeu.org/article/productivity-slowdown-even-more-puzzling-you-think#.WZ7AYeC56C0.gmail

The productivity slowdown is even more puzzling than you think

David Byrne, Dan Sichel 22 August 2017

The growth in labour productivity – real output per hour worked – in the US slowed markedly around 2004. During the previous ten years, labour productivity in the business sector had risen at an annual average pace of more than 3%. Productivity received a boost from innovations in the production of digital information and communications technologies (ICT) and the spreading use of ICT across all sectors of the economy. Despite the apparent continuation of the digital revolution, productivity growth slowed to about 2% a year during 2004-2010 and then dropped to a paltry pace near just 0.5% during 2010-2016. Outside the US, labour productivity growth also declined in other advanced market economies.

If sustained, this sluggish pace would have dire consequences for future gains in living standards. Over long spans of time, increases in labour productivity are the fuel that boosts living standards and the main reason that material well-being is significantly higher today than 50 or 100 years ago. At a 2% pace, labour productivity would double every 35 years, while at a 0.5% pace, that doubling would take almost 140 years.

Economists have debated the reasons for the slowdown, though no consensus has emerged. Explanations generally fall into three categories. It is attributed to either supply-side accounts pointing to factors limiting the growth rate of potential output;1 demand-side stories highlighting inadequate demand or interactions between weak demand and sluggish growth of potential output;2 or, finally, measurement explanations arguing that the tools of economic measurement have not kept up with the digital revolution and that the slowdown is a figment of poor measurement.3

We suspect that this debate will not be resolved anytime soon. That being said, we want to refocus the discussion about measurement of the digital economy. While we agree that available evidence on mismeasurement does not provide an explanation of the productivity slowdown, we also believe that biases in measures of ICT are significant and that this mismeasurement has important implications for economic growth in the future. In particular, we argue that innovation is much more rapid than would be inferred from official measures and that these on-going gains in the digital economy make the productivity slowdown even more puzzling. At the same time, we believe that this continued technical advance could provide the basis for a future pickup in productivity growth.

Are we mismeasuring the digital economy?

The short answer is yes. A key challenge to measuring changes in real GDP over time is correctly deflating nominal GDP to account for changes in prices. Getting price changes right for ICT production and investment is particularly difficult. And, as highlighted in Byrne et al. (2017), official measures of prices point to very slow rates of decline in the prices of high-tech products. But, a growing literature indicates that prices of ICT are actually falling much faster. For example, Byrne et al. (forthcoming) developed a new price index for microprocessors used in desktop computers. Their index fell at an average annual rate of 42% during 2009-13, while the most comparable official price index – the Producer Price Index – reports an average decline of 6% during the same period. Other research points to mismeasurement for other ICT products as well. Byrne and Corrado (2016) provide the best available measures of the amount of bias in official price indexes for high-tech products. Table 1 reports rates of change in official price indexes and the alternative research series for computers, communications equipment, software, and semiconductors reported by Byrne and Corrado (2016).4 As shown in the last column of the table, measurement gaps – which equal the difference between the percent changes of the official price index and the alternative research index – are sizeable for all of the high-tech products shown. Moreover, prices of many ICT products are still almost completely unstudied, including devices used in the medical, aerospace, and defence sectors and the industrial robots that have been the subject of much recent media attention.

Table 1 Official and alternative research price indexes for high-tech products, average percent change, 2004-2015

Note: Measurement gaps calculated as "official" less "alternative."

Source: Byrne et al. (2017). Official indexes for computing equipment, communications equipment, and software are from the Bureau of Economic Analysis; the official index for semiconductors is from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Alternative research indexes are from Byrne and Corrado (2016), including some details provided by the authors that are not reported in their paper.

In addition to ICT production, the digital economy encompasses an increasingly wide range of economic activity. The list is long and includes the myriad applications delivered by internet service providers, the energy exploration that relies on world class supercomputers to process seismic data, the surging e-commerce sector cannibalising shopping malls, the Hollywood movies produced with computer-generated imagery, the high resolution MRI, CT, and sonogram images that underpin advances in medical diagnosis, and many others. Developing price indexes that capture quality change for these industries is challenging. Moreover, the deep investment in ICT in all of the industries mentioned suggests that the official prices for their output, which in most cases show little change, may be missing something important.

Does this mismeasurement explain the productivity slowdown?

No. To explain the slowdown in labour productivity, either the amount of mismeasurement of productivity growth must have increased or the share of the mismeasured sectors must have risen. And recent research by Byrne et al. (2016) and Syverson (2017) has cast doubt on mismeasurement as an explanation of the productivity slowdown. While the amount of mismeasurement has increased in some areas, there was a lot of mismeasurement of high-tech before 2004 as well. And the production of many ICT products has shifted outside the US, reducing the GDP share of these products.

This answer was confirmed by Byrne et al. (2017). They use a detailed, multi-sector growth model to decompose growth in labour productivity into contributions from capital deepening (increases in the amount of capital available to each worker) and multifactor productivity (the amount by which output changes after accounting for changes in all inputs). Figure 1 shows this decomposition using both official price indexes (upper panel) and the alternative research price indexes described above (lower panel). As can be seen, switching from official price measures to the alternative research series has relatively little effect on the pattern of labour productivity growth over time, as well as the contributions from capital deepening and multifactor productivity (MFP). Byrne et al. (2017) focused on components of GDP that have been the subject of recent research attention. It is, of course, possible that mismeasurement elsewhere (either related or not related to the tech sector) could be biasing the pattern of labour and multifactor productivity in official measures.

Figure 1 Decomposition of labour productivity growth with official and alternative research prices, 1974-2015

Source: Byrne et al. (2017).

Does this mismeasurement matter?

Again, the answer is yes. Even though the mismeasurement of high-tech prices has little effect on the pattern of labour productivity growth across time, that mismeasurement has a dramatic effect on the allocation of MFP growth across sectors. As noted, MFP growth indicates the amount by which firms get better at transforming inputs into output. Along these lines, macroeconomists often use MFP growth as a rough proxy for the pace of innovation. MFP growth can be measured by comparing the growth rate of output to a weighted average of the growth rate of inputs. It also can be measured by comparing the price of output to a weighted average of changes in the prices of inputs (the so-called 'dual' approach). Borrowing the explanation from Sichel (2017), the logic of this approach can be seen in industries that experienced rapid technological progress. With fast MFP growth, an industry will be able, over time, to produce more output from a given set of inputs. If the cost of inputs is relatively stable, then those products should see their prices fall over time. For example, telecom has seen rapid price declines in recent decades. In 1952, a ten-minute daytime phone call from New York to Los Angeles cost about $48 in 2016 dollars.5 Today, phone companies do not even bother to separately price that call, and the call can be made from almost anywhere on a mobile phone rather than from a landline phone. These rapid price declines suggest that telecom experienced substantial growth in MFP.

Byrne et al. (2017) use this dual approach to measure MFP growth in high-tech industries (which include the production of computers, communications equipment, software, and semiconductors). Figure 2 compares the estimates of MFP growth generated using official price measures (the blue cross-hatched bars) and the alternative research price indexes (the red bars). As shown, MFP growth in the high-tech sector is considerably more rapid using the alternative research prices. This pattern indicates that the innovation has been much faster in the high-tech sector than indicated by official measures and accords more consistently with casual impressions that the digital economy continues to be powered by ongoing advances.

Figure 2. Total tech sector MFP growth rates with official and alternative research prices, 1974-2015 (%)

Note: High-tech sector includes the production of computers, communications equipment, software, and semiconductors.
Source: Byrne et al. (2017).

Byrne et al. (2017) also use the dual approach to calculate the growth rate of MFP outside of the high-tech sector. As shown in Figure 3, these growth rates are much slower when the alternative research prices are used than when official measures are used. Thus, correcting the mismeasurement of high-tech prices leads to a reallocation of MFP growth across sectors toward high tech and away from the rest of the economy. This reallocation of MFP growth implies much faster innovation in the digital economy than implied by official measures.

Figure 3. Other output MFP growth rates with official and alternative research prices, 1974-2015 (%)

Source: Byrne et al. (2017).

A deeper puzzle, but hope for the future

This pattern of MFP growth makes the productivity slowdown even more puzzling. If the tech sector continues to innovate so rapidly, why has overall productivity growth been exceptionally sluggish? While it is possible that the challenges inherent in measuring output outside the ICT sector have suddenly worsened, we suspect that the answer depends importantly on the long lags necessary for innovations to diffuse through the economy and move the needle on overall productivity. This pattern of slow diffusion has been seen in the past both with electrification in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, as well as for semiconductors in the second half of the 20th century. We believe that the faster rates of innovation in high tech that are evident, once measurement biases have been corrected, could be the fuel for a future pickup in productivity growth.6

Authors' note: The views expressed in this article are those of the authors alone and not institutions with which they are affiliated. Sichel thanks the Bureau of Economic Analysis and National Telecommunications & Information Administration for financial support for related research on price measurement.

References

Branstetter, L, and D Sichel (2017), "The Case for an American Productivity Revival," Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Brief 17-26, June.

Byrne, D M, and C Corrado (2016), "ICT Prices and ICT Services: What Do They Tell Us about Productivity and Technology?" presented at CRIW/NBER Summer Institute.

Byrne, D M, J G Fernald, and M B Reinsdorf (2016), "Does the United States have a productivity slowdown or a measurement problem?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2016(1): 109-182.

Byrne, D M, S D Oliner, and D E Sichel (forthcoming), "How Fast Are Semiconductor Prices Falling?" Review of Income and Wealth, also available as FEDS working paper 2017-005, January 2017.

Byrne, D M, S D Oliner, and D E Sichel (2017), "Prices of High-Tech Products, Mismeasurement, and the Pace of Innovation", Business Economics 52(2(: 103-113.

Federal Communications Commission, Reference Book of Rates, Price Indices, and Household Expenditures for Telephone Service, March 1997.

Gordon, R J (2016), The Rise and Fall of American Economic Growth, Princeton University Press.

Mason, J W (2017), "What Recovery? The Case for Continued Expansionary Policy at the Fed," Roosevelt Institute, July 25.

Reifschneider, D, W Wascher, and D Wilcox (2013), "Aggregate Supply in the United States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy," FEDS working paper no. 2013-77, November.

Sichel, D E (2017), "The Productivity Slowdown is Even More Puzzling than You Think," Econofact, May 17.

Summers, L H (2014), "U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound," Business Economics 49(2): 65-73.

Syverson, C (2016), "Challenges to Mismeasurement Explanations for the U.S. Productivity Slowdown," NBER working paper 21974.

Endnotes

[1] See Gordon (2016) for one prominent version.

[2] Summers (2014) has written extensively about "secular stagnation" as an explanation. Mason (2017) and Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2013) have argued that weak demand has restrained advances in potential output.

[3] For example, Goldman Sachs (2015 and 2016), argue that we are missing growth in key components of GDP, and Byrnjolfsson and Oh (2013) make the case that economic welfare is growing faster than real GDP.

[4] Note that the semiconductor index shown in the table incorporates the microprocessor index described above but also includes other semiconductors.

[5] For the cost in 1952, see Federal Communications Commission (1997: 62). The adjustment to today's dollars was done with the price deflator for personal consumption expenditures.

[6] For a more complete explication of the case for a revival in US productivity, see Branstetter and Sichel (2017).

What’s (not) up with productivity growth? A quick overview [feedly]

I always like Jared Bernstein's accessible summaries of complex but profound topics like innovation and productivity. Both of these have large economic consequences, but also have significant, less-understood non-economic dimensions. Intangibles (e.g. software) and many services have "values" not fully, or perhaps even adequately, expressed in their price. What's the true value of a health worker's time that saves your life -- considered in either economic or subjective terms? What's the value of Marc Andressen's Mosaic (later Netscape/Mozilla) Internet Browser -- in a "market environment" where code could be copied for free?

Interesting to ponder Bernstein's own preference (despite affirming that "no one knows") for a possible market failure in the slowness of old industries to fully integrate new technologies. He also tends to give a push to demand-side explanations: e.g. there's less innovation and productivity enhancing products and services because people can't afford to increase their consumption at old rates.




Jared Bernstein


For a long while now, I've been thinking and reading about the great productivity growth slowdown, so it seemed like a good time to give the lay of the land as I see it:

–Facts of the case, 1: As measured (as you'll see, this caveat is important), since 2010, output per hour has been growing about 1% per year, half the growth rate of the long-term average. Slowdowns of similar magnitudes have occurred across most advanced economies.

–Facts of the case, 2: The bulk of the slowdown is attributable to a decline in total factor productivity (TFP), or the growth in output when you take out all the measurable inputs. TFP is reasonably considered a proxy for innovation.

–The dreaded "empty hole problem:" Outside of accounting exercises that raise as many questions as they answer, economists do not understand the underlying forces that make productivity speed up and slow down. This creates the "empty hole problem:" since no one knows the answer, partisans fill the hole with their favorite candidate. E.G., here in DC "tax cuts and deregulation!" become the solution du jour.

–Optimists and (sort of) pessimists: When it comes to how lasting our plodding productivity growth rates will be, commentators fit roughly into pessimistic and optimistic camps. The pessimists are the larger group and, at least in my judgement, have better evidence. Their focus is on the slowdown in TFP, and for all the talk about it, no one really knows what drives innovation cycles. In that sense, "who knows?" is a subgroup among the pessimists wherein I place myself. The real pessimist caucus is chaired by the productivity expert Robert Gordon, who argues that the big-ticket productivity movers—e.g., electricity diffusion, air conditioning, indoor plumbing, air travel—are long behind us. Candy Crush is a fun, free diversion, but it ain't a big efficiency play.

–What about mismeasurement? The optimists largely depend on mismeasurement and they bring some evidence to the table. Since we're talking about growth rates, showing evidence of mismeasurement alone is not proof of anything. It must be shown that mismeasurement is getting worse, i.e., that we're increasingly leaving out value added in our measures of real output. Some mismeasurement claims stem from the observation that sectors wherein it is harder for national accountants to pick up true declines in quality-adjusted prices—health care, software, the "app" economy—are the very sectors that are growing as a share of value added, meaning even constant mismeasurement in those sectors could lead to downward bias in measured output and thus productivity.

The biggest mismeasurement advocates are the typically hard-nosed economics team at Goldman Sachs. The figure below shows their portentous adjustments to output from significantly goosing the quality adjustments to IT hardware, software, and "free digital content." Based on this work, they conclude that both GDP and productivity growth are understated by 1/4-1/2 percentage points, which is big in this biz.

Source: GS Research

However, I don't find all their adjustments fully convincing. Careful research points out that we're doing a better job than we used to measuring hardware and software, thus the productivity slowdown may be understated (in the US, we're also producing less IT hardware). Other work finds that, yes, our price indices are missing tech improvements, such that TFP in that sector has hardly slowed at all. But this just implies that TFP outside of tech has decelerated even faster than we thought. Then there's research showing that productivity is falling across many countries, and its decline is uncorrelated with their production of IT.

Also, a bunch of what's allegedly being increasingly mismeasured – e.g., the value of software – are intermediate goods, meaning you've got to show the links in the chain such that final demand is increasingly biased down.

Wherein I fill the empty hole: Here are three explanations that make sense to me. First, some of the most interesting research in this space shows an historically unique divergence between the productivity growth of so-called "frontier" and "laggard" firms. Why has the latter failed to adopt the technologies of the former, and why hasn't that failure led to their demise? This may be an important market failure.

Second, though the productivity slowdown predates the Great Recession, "secular stagnation" has been upon the land for quite a while now, and thus it might be a mistake to reject the hypothesis that weak demand is a factor. I can think of a simple, intuitive model wherein strong demand boosts unit labor costs, squeezing unit profits, such that maintaining profit margins means finding ways to produce more efficiently (this is the "full employment productivity multiplier" about which I've theorized). Third, the most accurate forecasts of productivity growth over the next few years require the use of very long—as in 40 years—autoregressive lags, so perhaps we will eventually mean-revert back to healthier productivity growth rates.

That last point is in the spirit of the most honest answer: who knows?


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Fwd: DSA Members Comment on Their 2017 Convention


---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: "Portside moderator" <moderator@portside.org>
Date: Aug 24, 2017 10:39 PM
Subject: DSA Members Comment on Their 2017 Convention
To: <PORTSIDE@lists.portside.org>
Cc:

 
 

 


August 24, 2017
Portside
 
Portside anticipated that the DSA convention would be a watershed event for the left. Just before it was called to order, membership surpassed 25,000. The group was making a leap from minor to major, and we welcomed that. We contacted some DSAers we know who were present, to bring you their views on what the meeting meant for DSA and the left.
 
 

., .,
 
 

 

In preparation, we invited a broad range of members, geographically and ideologically, including a few identified with the main contending tendencies at the convention. All the responses we received are included.

We edited out duplicate mentions of two controversies: the vote to endorse the Boycott, Divest and Sanction campaign, and the vote to disaffiliate from the Socialist International.

We have also excised comments about another controversy that broke out after the convention. A newly elected member of the National Political Committee has been targeted after-the-fact - and also defended - by members and others, when it was noted that his candidate's statement did not mention work as an organizer for a police union affiliated with CWA in Texas years ago. This has created a firestorm online, and Portside intends to cover it in due time. We do not want to further inflame the debate at a particularly sensitive time for DSA.

We previously ran an extensive, exclusive report by NYC DSAer Heidi Chua.

Read below what Jim Williams, Sarah Mills, Jessie Mannisto, Marshall Mayer, Rosa Squillacote, Christine Riddiough, Tina Shannon, Simone Morgen, Randy Shannon, Micah Landau, and Peter Frase have to say. - Portside moderators

Jim Williams (South Sound in Tacoma): The 2017 convention of DSA was a real hum-dinger: 750 delegates were representing over 25,000 members.  DSA is now the largest socialist organization since the CP in the 1940s.  Many of you have now seen reports that indicate that this is no longer your father's DSA.  It supported BDS against Israeli Apartheid. It left the Socialist International.  It called for the abolition of prisons and many other motions that may have Michael Harrington spinning in his grave.
While rejecting the idea of an immediate third party, DSA deemphasized work in the Democratic Party and displayed more openness to independent and socialist candidates at the local level

The crowd was overwhelmingly young.  Most delegates had been members for only a few years – mostly drawn by the Bernie Sanders campaign.  Interestingly, their mood was to go far beyond Bernie's modest social democratic programs to more advanced socialism.

There were a number of slates that contested for office, principally Momentum and Praxis.  Frankly, I didn't find their positions to be that different. But both were to the left of anything DSA has had before. There were Solidarity members running as part of the Momentum slate.  Dual-memberships are accepted from non-democratic-centralist organizations.  Organizations such as Socialist Alternative, International Socialist Organization, Party of Socialism and Liberation, et al, are not welcomed as members – although there is co-operation at some local levels. As far as I can say, CCDS members are welcome. (There was no mention of the CPUSA.)

There are now 117 chapters or organizing committees in 49 states. (Texas has 10 chapters.) [Portside note: These numbers continue to increase.]
I think CCDS members, with their experience and understanding, could contribute a lot to this new DSA.

The DSA convention did not do much on international questions beyond its support of BDS and its withdrawal from the Socialist International. However, there were speakers from Spain's PODEMOS, Portugal's LEFT BLOC, Jean-Luc Mélenchon's LA FRANCE INSOUMISE, and Jeremy Corbyn's MOMENTUM faction within the UK Labour Party. All of which gives an idea of DSA's orientation to international issues and alliances.

 

Sarah Mills (New York City): As a newer member of DSA – although I predate the post-election contingent by three whole months, making me practically a veteran – the 2017 Convention was my first, as it was for many others. The theme of "25,000 members" was predominant – I believe there may have been a requirement that every proposed resolution reference DSA's "massive growth" in its preamble.

Having spent the previous two months engaged in internal chapter conversations about not only the merits of the resolutions but the anticipated opposition, there were a few standout highlights – namely, the fact that we managed to leave the Socialist International and endorse BDS with only 20 minutes of debate apiece. Similarly, I am incredibly proud that the Afrosocialist and POC Caucus proposal passed with zero speakers in opposition.

Because massive growth poses challenges, I was pleased to see that a proposal for official grievance procedures at both the national and chapter level passed handily. Additionally, as an opponent of mandatory monthly dues (which the propagators of the proposal repeatedly stressed were not mandatory), I thought the membership made a solid decision to vote down a Constitutional amendment to that effect,  in favor of a more lenient resolution.

One of my favorite passed resolutions called for a national training program that would send seasoned organizers to train newer, smaller chapters – which will be key in Republican states where DSA has the capacity to launch serious opposition to tea party politics. This training program is deliberately designed to facilitate the exchange of information between newer and more established chapters, so it is not a top-down system. The trainings will evolve, incorporating lessons about strategy from younger and more isolated chapters, and will create more trainers to go forth and run their own regional trainings as new locals continue to form all over the country.

Some of these trainings were on display during the convention as well. I had the pleasure of running an Organizing 101 module with fantastic people from all over the country, as well as a 103 training on the "Member Mobilizer" program which was designed by members from my own branch. The mobilizer program is a way of organizing internally and activating current members through the intentional development of personal relationships which we have been developing in NYC since February. Mobilizers were mentioned in the platforms of both the Praxis and Momentum slates, and judging from the turnout at our informal "Mobilizer Caucus" and the training module, chapters all over the country have already been thinking about doing this and are excited to pilot the program for themselves.

 

 

Jessie Mannisto (Metro Washington, DC): I was one of several delegates who arrived late after a storm led to the cancellation of several flights.  By the time I made it to the convention floor on Friday afternoon, my fellow delegates — and wow were there a lot of delegates — were already well into Robert's Rules of Order.

This was my second DSA convention and my second time participating in this sort of direct democracy.  And it's truly a thrill.  Our votes matter, and as delegates, we all took our choices very seriously — which is why some of my favorite moments of the convention were the statements by comrades who courageously argued against some very popular resolutions.  Two who stood out in my mind were Enrique Calvo, who delivered a well-researched call to remain in the Socialist International, and Maxine Phillips, who voiced concerns about the full BDS resolution, such as the need to support Israeli peace activists.  As a delegate who went back and forth on these issues, I was grateful to them for standing up in front of that enormous room to share unpopular perspectives — something that is never easy to do, even among comrades who won't hold it against you.  That we have members who are willing to do so speaks to the strength of our organization.  I look forward to this continuing under DSA's big tent in locals across the country and at our future conventions.

 

Marshall Mayer (Helena, MT): Radical democracy scales well! That was demonstrated in full measure by the 700 delegates to the Democratic Socialists of America's (DSA) recent National Convention in Chicago. For the vast majority of delegates, this was their first DSA convention. For all of us, this was the first time American socialists conducted a truly democratic meeting of this size in decades, if ever. The result of extraordinary organizing by staff and voluntary leadership over several months, the convention managed to democratically address some very contentious issues, all in a comradely manner. By the time we all sang the Internationale at the end, we were again united around our political priorities. And we had elected the youngest and most politically diverse national leadership in DSA history.

What we all do tomorrow as democratic socialists in our communities, however, is far more important than what we did as delegates last weekend. And nowhere is this more important than for the new national leadership. The National Political Committee will be challenged to keep together the various political tendencies that make up the "big tent" of DSA. Our consistent commitment to pluralism, both political and in praxis, is largely responsible for DSA's dramatic growth since the 2015 convention, making us the largest socialist organization in America since the late-1940s. First among the NPC's priorities should be retaining the nearly 20,000 new members who have not yet been asked to renew their membership.

Rather than striving to stake the correct "left" position on any number of issues, the new NPC's focus needs to be on building the capacity of chapters to democratically organize for independent political power in their communities, based on the diverse local priorities of working and poor people, especially women and people of color. Only with the renewed commitment of our engaged members can we double our membership, as well as the number of chapters, before the next convention (an oft-repeated goal at this convention). That is DSA's challenge. We'll have to do at least that, between every convention for the foreseeable future, before a mass democratic socialist movement can truly be a national and majoritarian force capable of transcending capitalism in our lifetimes.

 

 

Rosa Squillacote (New York City – Young Democratic Socialists of America): The YDSA conference was held on the second day, and did not overlap with any delegate voting (although this was an accident of time and objection rather than scheduling). A new YDSA chair committee was voted in, with an explicit call to engage in developing a stronger internal infrastructure as well as building political relationships with DSA. This was mainly articulated in the Activist Agenda adopted at the conference. The question about building YDSA's relationship with DSA created some debate: some in the room felt that YDSA should develop its own priorities and political independence, others felt that YDSA should collapse into a youth caucus of DSA. YDSA was originally meant to be politically distinct from DSA, and the question now is how we should reconstitute a relationship with DSA.

Two resolutions were passed, the first of which endorsed a congressional bill for free college tuition for all. This was amended to include language calling for "free and fully funded" college.

The second resolution articulated in greater detail the mentorship/training program of the Activist Agenda. This was amended to indicate the mutual teaching/learning dynamic of YDSA and DSA. This amendment added the phrase "mutual mentorship" where appropriate.

(An aside: a young man sitting next to me – a graduating high school senior – indicated some trepidation at this: what can we teach adults? Yet throughout the conference, this young man kept explaining to me the definition and also the purpose behind various technical points of parliamentary procedure. I suggested he write a YDSA 101 guide on this topic, and hopefully he will do so!)

Two amendments were debated and passed. The first formally changed the name from YDS to YDSA. The second was a more thorough re-working of the YDSA constitution, and included changes regarding the age of elected YDSA members; city and state-wide YDSA chapters and groups, and a requirement that the annual YDSA conference not be at the same time as the DSA convention.

 

Tina Shannon (Steel Valley DSA Organizing Committee, Pennsylvania): For me the most exciting part of the DSA Convention was the Single-Payer workshop I attended.  I usually feel antsy in a workshop made entirely of presentations. This time, not so. It consisted mostly of accounts of lived organizing experience.

It opened with an organizer from the East Bay Chapter in California. He gave his 7-minute rap on single-payer which was engaging and informative, even for those of us already experienced in the field. This should be recorded so we can use it.

His comrades from the Bay Area gave a moving account of their organizing experiences, of how they were surprised by their first announced healthcare meeting drawing over 30 people, and then their very next one drawing a couple hundred. They teared up as they told of their folks experiencing the work as life-changing, of now having 50 team leaders and having knocked on 10,000 doors. I teared up too.

Brooklyn reported a bit about the intricacy of the work in their city. I later found out that they have had so much new membership that they've had to split into 3 chapters for Brooklyn.

A young woman from Texas told of being the furthest left person in her hometown and then moving to Houston. She talked about planning an event and getting a big venue and filling it. She gave details of allies who worked with them, and of one often reliable liberal who usually voted the right way but nonetheless organized a competing rally to support the ACA. Success and inspiration from the South too.

The entire workshop was inspiring and informative and life-giving. Thank you to the young organizers who put it together.

 

 

Christine Riddiough (Washington, DC and National Political Committee): So many people, so much energy have rarely been seen at a socialist meeting in the US. Perhaps the only event that rivals it was the Socialist Feminist conference held in Yellow Springs, Ohio in 1975.

This convention achieved many things, not the least of which is the passage of DSA priorities for the next two years. Those priorities – health care, labor organizing, and electoral politics – were quickly put on the back burner when the fascist actions in Charlottesville happened so soon after. DSA members and leaders have gotten back to work fighting these latest attacks from the right.

As this work continues, national leadership will develop a program to enact the priorities adopted by the convention. In doing so we have to consider this in the context of a strategy for the next 20 years. Without such a strategy, the left, of which DSA is now the central organization, will continue in the manner we have for decades – saying we aren't big enough to have an impact on elections, on issues, on politics. It will be a self-fulfilling prophecy – we can't do something because we're too small and we're too small because we can't do anything.

It doesn't have to be that way. Let me take you back to 1964. Barry Goldwater suffered a devastating loss to Lyndon Johnson in the Presidential election. Goldwater was, for that time, a hard-right politician; his loss was viewed as wreaking havoc on the right. Sixteen years later Ronald Reagan was elected President. Over the course of the 1970s the right had a strategy. It took Goldwater's base in the South and turned it into 'a Southern strategy,' a strategy that allowed it to put Ronald Reagan in the White House in 1980. In doing this it was able to capture the debate on the role of government – in 1972 Congress voted for a universal child care bill (vetoed by President Nixon), eight years later the mantra was becoming 'get the government off my back.'

What does this have to do with DSA? In sixteen years, we'll be inaugurating a President, swearing in new members of Congress and state legislatures. We need to start laying the groundwork now for a democratic socialist victory in the future. Without some vision of the future, we'll be doing the same thing we are now – setting two-year priorities, trying to get healthcare for all, fighting the right on public education and not making any progress.

That 20-year strategy must critically consider the question of power. In order to bring about the changes we want, to move the US in direction of democratic socialism, we need power. In Socialist Feminism: A Strategy for the Women's Movement, a position paper of the Chicago Women's Liberation Union from 1972, the importance of power is described: 'The socialist feminist strategy aims at realigning power relations through the process of building a base of power for women…. We oppose the utopian position which argues against any change until the perfect solution is possible.'

They go on to describe the three criteria for choosing issues:

1.       They should materially alter women's lives.

2.       They should give women a sense of their own power.

3.       They should alter the relations of power.

We have to consider our efforts in that kind of context. Political power to enact the changes we want isn't going to come from electing Bernie Sanders or anyone else president. In order for the future democratic socialist president of the United States to be able to achieve anything, there must be backup – senators, members of the House, state governors and legislators who will support a democratic socialist agenda.

That means that DSA will need to enter into the electoral arena. It will likely involve protests against current policies and politics, as well as proactively building a full democratic socialist agenda. And it will mean that DSA must support candidates in the local and state races where future senators and presidents are made. As DSA goes forward from the convention the work on this and the other priorities will test the organization's strength and resilience. DSA now has the potential to build toward real power, real socialism.

 

Simone Morgen (Columbus, OH): As a veteran of several conventions, my most salient impression in this gathering was its sheer energy and size in comparison to those I had experienced, as well as the greatly increased number of those generally considered to be millennials. The sheer number of proposals, amendments and resolutions put forth dwarfed those in past conventions.  This reflects the enthusiasm of new members, many brought by the Bernie campaign/Trump election, who have no shortage of ideas.  Debating and deciding on these was certainly an exercise of concentration and effort, ably handled by some of our best parliamentarians. Differences of opinion arose, as would necessarily be the case in the wide range of opinions and viewpoints in the DSA "large tent."  How we can resolve these going forward, and build on the surge we have experienced is undoubtedly the key question, although given the current state of American affairs, we really have no choice but to work to craft a movement that will last.

 

Randy Shannon (Steel Valley DSA Organizing Committee, Pennsylvania): There were a few interesting disputations towards the end. There was debate over a proposal to establish a training program. The opposition felt it was poorly conceived and unrelated to real campaigns around issues. That vote was the first to receive a hand count. The motion passed 313 to 303.

The opening plenary on socialist strategy was very satisfying for me with a national campaign for single payer, a two fisted fight against the right and the neoliberals, support for union organizing in Mississippi, support for undocumented workers, and stepping up the fight against racism.

It looks like the convention is 70% millennials, 40% women, and 5% people of color. There is a significant LGBTQ contingent. At this point no factionalism has reared its head. The glue is the massive DSA effort around winning Medicare for All.

A workshop on single payer was standing room only with powerful stories by presenters from CA, NY, and TX. DSA locals are spearheading a grass roots mobilization for single payer across the country. Members recognize it as a "revolutionary reform" that frees an economic sector from control of capital. Here in PA, DSA is moving into this campaign.

The convention passed a resolution making single payer a national campaign for DSA. An ultra-left faction tried to amend to say DSA could work with individual Democrats but not with progressive groups like Our Revolution or Progressive Democrats of America because they "support capitalism." That amendment got around 300 votes, which surprised me, but was defeated by close to 100 votes.

I attended a workshop on socialist strategy. There were 40 folks from around the country. I assumed we would be talking about terrains of struggle, the major hegemonic and counter-hegemonic forces, points of weakness and strength, blah blah to move toward socialism. But the discussion was about 1) how to educate new members with an emphasis on not having to read books and 2) how to recruit members from minority sectors.

My assessment is 20,000 young people joined this socialist group all at once. They held meetings and realized they were almost all "white." So their vision of strategy is fulfilling the necessity of growing into a multinational socialist organization tout suite, with little time to read books.

 

 

Micah Landau (New York City): One important development has, in my view, been widely overlooked, or seen as negative: the emergence of slates for national leadership.

The political differences between Momentum and Praxis - the two main slates at the convention - are important, but most important was their mere existence, a first for DSA as far as I am aware.

In the small organizations to which many of us are accustomed, most members, if not all, know each other and where we each stand on the most important issues. In DSA that's no longer possible.

In this context, the existence of slates - mistakenly viewed by many as divisive - made clear the political alliances that exist in the organization and allowed members to deduce candidates' political positions via these alliances.

It was impossible during a single weekend to get to know all 43 candidates for leadership. Nor, I felt, did their candidate statements provide sufficient information to make an informed decision. The slates served as a sort of cheat sheet; delegates who knew and agreed with the politics of one or two members of a slate could, if they wanted, simply vote the slate (as I did).

While many members - both younger members new to left organizations but also some older members who themselves know firsthand the destructive potential of factionalism - expressed wariness about the emergence of slates, they in fact represent an important step toward true political elections in the new DSA and away from elections in which many independent candidates ran without defined programs and many delegates, left with precious little time to get to know candidates, voted largely on name recognition.  

Slates and caucuses - which I hope both Momentum and Praxis will become - can certainly be divisive, but they don't have to be. At their best, they sharpen those political differences that need to be sharpened - and there are many of those inside DSA's new, bigger-than-ever tent - without tearing the organization apart.

"Factions" will in any case always exist. Their organization into formal groups brings them out of the shadows, where they inevitably exist as informal social networks, making the entire organization more transparent and creating important avenues for members to find others who share their vision for the organization and want to organize to see it realized.

Rather than fear their development or reject it as "divisive" we ought to embrace the emergence of caucuses in DSA as integral elements of a truly democratic big-tent organization.

 

Peter Frase (Lower Hudson Valley, NY): I joined DSA in 1998, when I arrived as an undergraduate at the University of Chicago. I was already a committed Marxist, perhaps mixed with a bit of anarchism. But I took to heart the notion that "an unorganized socialist is a contradiction in terms." So I identified DSA as the least sectarian and most politically relevant of the groups on offer; I duly walked up to their table at freshman orientation week and recruited myself.

After college, I stayed involved intermittently, although nobody would have called me a particularly committed cadre. I had a sense that DSA was adrift, continuing on more by inertia than by any real sense of political purpose. And so it was, a decade or so ago, that I started to have the conversation with other comrades around my age: how do we let DSA die? That is, how do we acknowledge that this project has reached its terminus, without discarding the accumulated skill and knowledge of the comrades who do still have something to contribute to building 21st Century socialism?

Then the membership exploded, chapters popped up all over, and everything was uncertain. For the first time in years, I went to a DSA convention. And for the first time ever, I was an official voting delegate.

And I watched, on that August weekend in Chicago, as DSA finally did die, to thunderous applause. And I couldn't be happier about it.

Yes, the name and the organizational structure continue on, but what DSA is - and who it is - has been radically transformed in a matter of months. Of the 800 delegates in Chicago, the vast majority are newcomers to the organization. At the convention banquet, the MC asked us to stand sequentially according to the period when we had become involved in DSA or its predecessors: the 1970s, the 1980s, the 1990s, the 2000s, the early 2010s, or since the beginning of 2016. Until that very last call, almost everyone was seated.

With such an inexperienced and untested group, there was no way of knowing how anyone would react. Would they be angered or bewildered at having to debate resolutions through the arcane procedure of Robert's Rules of Order? Would some kind of wacky thing get passed as an official DSA position? Would we manage to agree on anything at all?

In the end, the assembled delegates acquitted themselves as well as I could possibly have hoped. People got the hang of the rules, votes mostly proceeded smoothly. And most importantly, the substantive decisions made were, from my point of view, almost all the right ones. And some of them would have been hard to imagine coming from the old DSA.

Perhaps the most encouraging thing I saw all weekend, however, was what took place during the final parliamentary session on Sunday. Throughout the convention, comrades with disabilities had become increasingly frustrated with what they felt was a lack of accessibility and acknowledgment of their issues during the proceedings. On Sunday, they decided to make a forceful intervention.

This was an extremely fraught moment. The protest immediately divided the room, with some delegates furious at the chair, and others furious at the protesters. I confess that I myself wavered for a moment, and I was afraid that the entire proceeding was about to devolve into chaos. But I soon realized that what was at stake, at that moment, was far more politically significant than keeping to a schedule or voting on a few remaining resolutions. This was about whether we, as the assembled delegates of DSA, were going to show some flexibility in order to affirm our solidarity with our comrades with disabilities, and by extension with all those who may find themselves marginalized or excluded in DSA.

And I'm proud to say that we passed this test. Our Robert's Rules acumen had been sharpened by days of parliamentary procedure, and someone quickly realized that we had the authority to vote to overturn the chair's ruling to clear the protesters from the hall. After that, a motion on disability language was affirmed by huge margins, order returned, and we proceeded with the agenda. That one moment isn't sufficient to address the larger issues raised by the protesting comrades, of course. But I'm hopeful that it was a sufficient display of solidarity to avoid permanently alienating some of our most committed members.

It remains to be seen whether the current burst of enthusiasm can be sustained, or if it was just a flash in the pan. But for now, at least, I've been convinced that the historic rebirth I've long dreamed of is a reality.

DSA is dead. Long live DSA!

 


 

 
 
VIEW ONLINE
PRINT
SUBSCRIBE
VISIT PORTSIDE.ORG
TWITTER
FACEBOOK

 

 
 

Portside aims to provide material of interest to people on the left that will help them to interpret the world and to change it.

       
 

To unsubscribe, click here.