Wednesday, August 19, 2020

College Admissions Are About to Get Even More Unfair [feedly]

College Admissions Are About to Get Even More Unfair
https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2020-08-19/college-admissions-are-about-to-get-even-more-unfair

The issue of college admissions is once again in the news. President Donald Trump's Justice Department has alleged that Yale University's use of race as a criterion for undergraduate admissions violates civil rights law. The accusation is sure to provoke lots of bitter ideological and partisan argument, and it will eventually have to be resolved by the courts.

But it also offers us an occasion to think carefully about the purpose of college admissions — what ought to determine who gets into top schools, and what actually does determine it. There's much that's unfair about the process, and the pandemic will only make that unfairness more acute.

Many people seem to assume it's fair for colleges to choose students based on abilities. But does society really gain from showering educational resources on those who are already good at school? And to the extent college is about networking, it seems counterproductive to have all the most capable people hang out and form friendships and marriages with all the other most capable people. Finally, there's no guarantee educational resources translate into workplace productivity; it's possible elite colleges funnel the nation's best and brightest toward occupations such as finance and consulting, where they add less value.

The argument for meritocracy in college admissions is that higher-ability people -- be they smarter, more driven, or whatever -- are better able to utilize the resources higher-ranked schools provide. Smart people may be more capable of handling the classes at Yale than the classes at Eastern Connecticut State University. In this view, a mismatch between the level of education and the level of student ability would simply lead to frustration, dropouts, and wasted resources.

More from

So the question of who deserves to get into highly ranked colleges is a difficult one, and is unlikely to be resolved any time soon. But universities don't act for the good of society; they have their own selfish motivations. And one big motivation is money.

Universities get their funding from three main sources: government, tuition, and donations. Government funding has fallen since the turn of the century, with federal spending increasing slightly but state spending never fully recovering after the Great Recession. In general, universities get only a modest fraction of their total financial needs from the government; elite private schools such as Yale naturally get even less, as they're private.

That leaves tuition and donations. College tuition has increased over the years, but not nearly as much as people think. For example, at private nonprofit institutions, which includes elite schools, net tuition — the price students actually pay — is about the same as it was at the turn of the century:

No Grade Inflation Here

Instead of raising prices overall, these universities have raised the price they charge wealthy students, while using need-based financial aid to hold down the price paid by students of modest means.

But this gives universities an obvious incentive to admit more students from rich families. Under the need-based financial-aid system, a rich student is a profit center while a poor student represents a financial loss.

Donations have also become an important source of colleges' revenue, and more so for elite schools such as Yale. Alumni and philanthropic foundations (which are often controlled by alumni) are the two biggest sources of donations. As wealthier alumni are more likely to give bigger gifts, colleges have a financial incentive to admit the people they think will have the best chance of getting rich in the future.

So who's more likely to get rich — a smart kid from a modest background, or a rich kid of modest ability? Increasingly, the latter. A recent study by Georgetown's Center on Education and the Workforce found that kids from wealthy backgrounds with low test scores were far more likely to be well-off by early adulthood than kids from low-income families with high test scores. Intergenerational economic mobility has been falling in the U.S. for quite some time. All this means that for a university, picking tomorrow's rich alumni increasingly means picking today's rich parents.

Thus, while affirmative action opponents want universities to take high-ability students, and affirmative action supporters want universities to take underprivileged students, universities' actual financial incentive is to take neither of these, and instead to take students from wealthy families.

The easiest way to do this, of course, is legacy admissions; according to some sources, about one third of Harvard's incoming freshman class in 2019 were legacies. Certain sports that are mostly played by the wealthy, such as fencing and golf, are another way elite schools pick out rich kids.

Whatever your position on meritocracy vs. diversity, this seems like a clearly unfair outcome. The fair thing to do would be to ban legacy admissions and scale back admissions based on elite sports. But colleges have every economic incentive to keep betting on oligarchy.

Of course, colleges care about more than dollars — they care about their reputation and their moral mission to improve society. But with the pandemic squeezing every source of university funding, these institutions will have less leeway to pursue their higher calling.

Coronavirus will push colleges even more toward admitting the scions of wealthy families, at the expense of both the high-ability and the under-privileged. Barring a dramatic increase in federal government funding, it seems very likely college admissions will only become less fair in the years to come.

    This column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.

    To contact the author of this story:
    Noah Smith at nsmith150@bloomberg.net


     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Should We Be More Worried About the Economy? [feedly]

    Should We Be More Worried About the Economy?
    http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/beat_the_press/~3/fwfqf53pQwM/

    We are really in an unprecedented period where the economy is trying to recover from the shutdowns of April and May, while being faced with partial shutdowns due to the resurgence of the pandemic in large parts of the country. We are struggling to make sense of data, which often has a substantial lag. We are still getting data from July even as we are in the last weeks of August. Furthermore, when we have large monthly changes, the picture at the end of July could have been very different than the beginning of the month.

    The Opportunity Insights program at Harvard University is trying to help navigate the storm with its Economic Tracker. This provides much more current data on a variety of measures by relying on various industry sources. The latest picture is not good.

    Starting with the one I find most troubling, their source on job posting shows a huge falloff in August. Nationally, we are almost back to the lows reached in May.

    There is the qualification that these are posting at small businesses, so perhaps the story would look different if we included and mid-sized and large businesses, but still this picture is not encouraging. Their data on small businesses that are open and revenue are also not good.

    The other very disturbing item is their data on consumer spending, which is derived from credit and debit card spending.

    The data show a healthy bounce back in June, but then spending levels off in July. Then, spending begins to trail off at the end of the month and start of August. Note that this is just as unemployment insurance supplements are ending.

    These are new data sources that I and most other economists are not familiar with. That means that there can be quirks that explain the plunge in job postings and falloff in spending that we do know about. But on its face, these data suggest a recovery that is stalling, with many businesses closing and millions of workers not being able to go back to their  jobs.

    That should make the case for a new rescue package more urgent and also again remind us of the importance to the economy of bringing the pandemic under control.


     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Tuesday, August 18, 2020

    Reforming Unemployment Insurance across the United States [feedly]

    Reforming Unemployment Insurance across the United States
    https://equitablegrowth.org/reforming-unemployment-insurance-across-the-united-states/

    Longstanding problems with the Unemployment Insurance system in the United States are immediately evident amid the coronavirus recession and echo the problems experienced during the Great Recession more than a decade ago. These include:

    • Administrative failures at state Unemployment Insurance agencies
    • Lack of a permanent Unemployment Insurance program that includes the self-employed and others traditionally left out of the program
    • Low benefit levels that require emergency top-offs
    • The temporary nature of fixes when recessions hit, which, in turn, requires renegotiations just months after political compromises are reached

    The current disarray in the Unemployment Insurance system is neither a surprise nor an accident. It is the result of decades of conscious choices made by policymakers at the state and federal levels: Over the past decade, many states limited Unemployment Insurance benefits, made accessing the program more difficult, and allocated insufficient funds for program administration. This results in chaos and uncertainty just when Unemployment Insurance is critical to prevent deterioration in the wider economy and save families from precarious financial situations.

    As in the Great Recession, states' trust funds are now being depleted, which sets the stage for the erosion of benefit levels while the crisis remains ongoing. And, as was the case in the Great Recession, in the first months of the coronavirus crisis, policymakers have yet to remedy the issues at the heart of these administrative failures.

    But it's not too late. Unemployment Insurance is a joint state-federal system. These programs are run at the state level but follow federal guidelines under the Social Security Act. Reforms to this system are important at both levels. The key resources below provide the details for enacting these reforms.

    Key resources

    "Unemployment Insurance reform: A primer," by Til von Wachter

    This primer summarizes how the Unemployment Insurance system functions in the United States and four ways it falls short. First, the current UI system suffers from financial instability that risks compromising its major role as a stabilizer in recessions. Second, the coverage of unemployment benefits has eroded over time, with a declining fraction of workers receiving lower benefits amounts. Third, the UI system does little to avert the large, long-lasting earnings losses among re-employed workers. And fourth, there are persistent questions about the effectiveness of Unemployment Insurance and related programs to quickly re-employ job losers. This primer lays out easy-to-implement small changes to address these problems, as well as fundamental changes to modernize the program.

    "Unemployment Insurance and macroeconomic stabilization," by John Coglianese and Gabriel Chodorow-Reich

    The authors lay out a plan for improving the Unemployment Insurance program's function as an anti-recessionary automatic stabilizer. They propose measures that increase take-up of regular unemployment benefits, full federal financing for extended benefits alongside improvements in the formula and design of extended benefits triggers, and an increase in the unemployment benefit amount when extended benefits are triggered.

    "Fool me once: Investing in Unemployment Insurance systems to avoid the mistakes of the Great Recession during COVID-19," by Alix Gould-Werth

    Gould-Werth presents a description of the problems in the Unemployment Insurance system exposed during the Great Recession and then repeated during the coronavirus crisis. She shows that policymakers have an opportunity to intervene and improve the functioning of the Unemployment Insurance system by increasing and indexing the federal taxable wage base, redesigning extensions to respond to economic changes quickly, and standardizing a minimum benefit level and duration that are sufficiently generous.

    "Factsheet: Unemployment Insurance and why the effect of work disincentives is greatly overstated amid the coronavirus recession," by Equitable Growth

    One of the biggest political obstacles to fixing the UI system is the fear that increasing access and generosity of benefits will discourage people from working. This Equitable Growth factsheet breaks down the research on work disincentives, showing that the amount of attention given to work disincentives (quite large) is disproportionate to the magnitude of the disincentives themselves, which are substantively small. At the same time, relatively little attention is paid to the benefits of Unemployment Insurance.

    Top experts

    • Alix Gould-Werth, director of family economic security policy, Washington Center for Equitable Growth
    • Kate Bahn, director of labor market policy, Washington Center for Equitable Growth
    • Till von Wachter, professor, Department of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles
    • Adriana Kugler, full professor, McCourt School of Public Policy, Georgetown University
    • Gabriel Chodorow-Reich, associate professor of economics, Harvard University
    • John Coglianeseeconomist, Federal Reserve Board of Governors
    • Jesse Rothstein, professor of public policy and economics, University of California, Berkeley, with affiliations in the Department of Economics and the Goldman School of Public Policy
    • Steve Woodbury, professor of economics, Michigan State University, and senior economist, W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research

     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Sunday, August 16, 2020

    How Externalities Affect Systems [feedly]

    Crises triggered by internal economic contradictions are distinguished from those that are triggered by external (to the economy)  events. The COVID crisis is of the latter category. The bubble-triggered 2008 financial crisis is of the former. However, the distinction is partial. Internal economic contradictions, such as the aggravated US economic inequalities, may not be the 2020 trigger, but will have no less profound impact on the response or recovery from the "externality". 

    Barry Ritholtz gives some good examples. However, note his response to predicting the future of this particular 'externality triggered' crisis: "I don't pretend to know"

    How Externalities Affect Systems

    https://ritholtz.com/2020/08/how-externalities-affect-systems/It took about a billion years for life – single cell organisms — to develop on planet earth. Another 500 million years led to simple organisms that used photosynthesis; another 1 – 2 billion years before multi-cellular life appeared. The next billion yearsled to plants, dinosaurs, birds and mammals.

    Evolution was the driving force of these changes. Suitability and adaptation was a key to competitive success. Life evolved so it could adapt to changing conditions. But every now and again, fate intervened, in the form of five mass extinctions.

    The most recent: About 66 million years ago, a 7.5-mile-wide asteroid traveling about 50,000 mph slammed into the earth in the ocean near Chicxulub, Mexico. The collision resulted in an explosion estimated at over 100 trillion tons of TNT. That's about a billion times more energy than the Hiroshima atomic bomb. The impact gouged the Earth's crust several miles deep and more than 115 miles long.1

    It was not a good day to be a dinosaur.

    Everything within 1,000 miles was killed by a giant fireball. That was followed by a 1,000-foot high tsunami, extinguishing the fires, and drowning anything that survived. Just in case a few creatures were still standing, a 600-mile an hour wind blast tore through the region. And that was just day one. Nuclear winter followed, chilling the planet by a global average of 14 to 18 degrees.2

    Eventually, the critters that could adapt to these circumstances did. Thus, the dinosaurs demise was soon followed by the rise of the mammals. And by soon, I mean 10s of millions of years.

    What does any of this have to do with markets, economics and investing?

    You might be surprised.

    I am entranced by the concept of how externalities intervene in functioning systems. In markets, usual variables affect the normal secular cycles. The ebb and flow of the economy, inflation, consumer spending, employment, fiscal and monetary policy, sentiment, interest rates, etc. all impact the longer cycle of price and value.

    What happens when an externality hits the markets like that asteroid from space? What happens when a non-economic event crashes into stocks and bonds, and derails their prior path? Consider some of history's externalities that have impacted markets:

    • 1914 Assassination of Archduke Franz Ferdinand, sparking WW1;

    • 1941 Attack on Pearl Harbor, bringing the US into WW2

    • 1963 Assassination President JFK

    • 2001 September 11 Terror Attacks on USA

    • 2011 Tōhoku earthquake and tsunami, leading to a full system failure at the Fukushima Daiichi Nuclear plant;

    • 2020 Covid-19 Pandemic, leading to a global lockdown.

    There are surely many more you can think of, but these six are the first ones that come to mind.

    In each of these cases in the past, when externalities hit, markets would wobble. Often, they would create a spike in fear that led to a sell off, fast and hard. But then, the markets would normalize, and simply resume their prior trend.

    That seems to be what is taking place currently: Covid 19 led to the fastest bear market in history, and the fastest snapback to prior highs. The move down was so deep that economically, none of the data could fit on the usual charts. I mentioned in April that we should not be too quick to assume the bull market was over, and so far, events seem to be confirming that view. Eventually, we will have a vaccine and a treatment for COVID.

    Which leads to an interesting question:

    When all this is over, will the FAANMG advantages stick? Or, will mean reversion occur, as the prior economic structures reassert themselves? Will the economic dinosaurs soon find themselves replaced by smarter, more adaptable mammals?

    I don't pretend to know, but I do find these questions fascinating.

    More on this next week.


     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Saturday, August 15, 2020

    US facing an ‘epic catastrophe’ of evictions and homelessness [feedly]

    US facing an 'epic catastrophe' of evictions and homelessness
    http://www.shanghaidaily.com/world/US-facing-an-epic-catastrophe-of-evictions-and-homelessness/shdaily.shtml

    Activists and relief groups in the United States are scrambling to head off a monumental wave of evictions nationwide, as the coronavirus crisis leaves tens of millions at risk of homelessness.The jobs catastrophe sparked by the global health emergency and the tepid rebound in the world's largest economy have left Americans struggling to pay rent and vulnerable to eviction.Hopes for relief in the form of a fresh aid package from Washington were dashed as partisan bickering scuppered the latest negotiations.The housing crisis is "already a tsunami," said Bambie Hayes-Brown of Georgia Advancing Communities Together, a coalition of non-profit housing and community development groups."We got some funding from the United Way and we went through it so fast. We were just inundated."Mariatou Diallo, who lives in New York, has not paid her rent since March, when her work in the health care industry dried up. The future frightens her."Right now, I'm very worried because I have an child and if I'm evicted, I don't know what I'm going to do," she said at a rally for rent relief in the Bronx.Weekly census data shows that more than 30 percent of renters in the United States have no or "slight" confidence in their ability to pay rent next month.The Aspen Institute estimated as many as 40 million people could be at risk of eviction in the coming months, leading to "destabilization of communities" across the country.Landlords have filed for nearly 35,000 evictions during the pandemic in 17 cities tracked by the Eviction Lab at Princeton University, although 10 of those cities are blocking the move.In some cases, renters have fallen months behind, but the crisis is only coming to a head now because eviction moratorium orders in several states have expired.In addition, housing courts have reopened after being shuttered for months due to restrictions to curb the spread of the coronavirus.Another factor is the ending on July 31 of federal unemployment benefits that provided US$600 a week to workers laid off due to the pandemic."Without the US$600, nobody can pay the rent," said Yudy Ramirez, who lost her job as a housekeeper at a Manhattan hotel in March.Ramirez, 46, has not made payments for July or August on her apartment in the Bronx, which costs US$1,100 a month. She has no news about possibly returning to her old job, and her health insurance benefits are about to lapse.The prospect of eviction looms especially threatening in working class, non-white neighborhoods like the Bronx, which have suffered more deaths from COVID-19 and experienced disproportionate job losses.About 50 people from the neighborhood including Diallo and Ramirez joined Monday's protest outside the Bronx Housing Court."It's a pandemic — moratorium now!" They chanted in English and Spanish, demanding that New York Governor Andrew Cuomo back legislation to forgive rent.John Pollock, coordinator of the National Coalition for a Civil Right to Counsel, said the US is facing an "epic catastrophe" on evictions, but that the situation could be mitigated by a fiscal package from Washington.The Democratic bill includes US$100 billion in rent relief, as well as an extension of unemployment benefits. But the Republicans balked at the deal.  

     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Restoring the federal estate tax is a proven way to raise revenue and address wealth inequality [feedly]

    Restoring the federal estate tax is a proven way to raise revenue and address wealth inequality
    https://equitablegrowth.org/restoring-the-federal-estate-tax-is-a-proven-way-to-raise-revenue-and-address-wealth-inequality/

     -- via my feedly newsfeed

    Cities as Economic Engines: Is Lower Density in our Future? [feedly]

    Cities as Economic Engines: Is Lower Density in our Future?
    https://conversableeconomist.blogspot.com/2020/08/cities-as-economic-engines-is-lower.html

    When studying urban economics, a common starting point is to make the obvious observation that economic activity does not have an even geographic distribution. Instead, it  clusters in metropolitan areas. To put it another way, even with higher real estate costs, higher wages and prices, traffic congestion, pollution, and crime, businesses find it economically worthwhile to locate in urban areas. For such firms, there must be some offsetting productivity benefit. The Summer 2020 issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives includes a four paper symposium on "Productivity Advantages of Cities." 

    Here, I'll focus on a few themes of the first two papers. But it's impossible to read the papers in late-summer 2020 without wondering if the productivity advantages of cities that they describe are going to be a casualty of public concerns over the pandemic and rising crime in urban areas. 

    Duranton and Puga provide an overview of the research on economic gains from population density. They write: 
    While urban economists broadly agree on the magnitude of the productivity benefits of density, the evidence distinguishing between possible sources is less solid. Duranton and Puga (2004) classify the mechanisms into three broad classes. First, a larger market allows for a more efficient sharing of local infrastructure, a variety of intermediate input suppliers, or a pool of workers. Second, a larger market also allows for better matching between employers and employees, or buyers and suppliers. Finally, a larger market can also facilitate learning, by facilitating the transmission and accumulation of skills or by promoting the development and adoption of new technologies and business practices.
    They also point out that these "agglomeration economies" at some point can be outweighed by costs of density like land prices, housing prices, transport costs, and congestion. 
    Theory has long hypothesized that as population and density increase in a city, its benefits initially accumulate faster, but eventually, its costs dominate (Henderson 1974). Fujita and Thisse (2013) call this the "fundamental trade-off of spatial economics," because it explains both the existence of cities and their finite sizes. However, compared to research on benefits of density, there is a paucity of research on its costs, which Glaeser (2011) dubbed the "demons of density."
    Rosenthal and Strange dig into some of the productivity advantages of density, and discuss the evidence that the gains of economic activity by being grouped together operate at many levels. For example, if one looks at a certain region, it's not just that economic activity is concentrated within the metropolitan area. In addition, there will be pockets of increased density within the overall urban area, like the Wall Street area in New York. And even within those pockets of higher density, there will be geographic concentrations of specific kinds of firms--like financial or legal or advertising firms--that are bunched within a few blocks or even on different floors in the same buildings.  At all of these different levels, there is evidence of productivity gains from being grouped together. They write: 
    Agglomeration effects operate at various levels of spatial aggregation, including regional, metropolitan, and neighborhood scales. In fact, there is also evidence that agglomeration effects operate below the neighborhood level, including within buildings and organizations. Although agglomeration effects can extend over broad distances, they also attenuate, with nearby activity exerting the strongest effect on productivity.
    For the last few months, the density of workplaces in the US economy has dramatically diminished.  Whatever the productivity benefits of density in cities, concerns over the pandemic and then also about prevalence of crime and rioting are causing firms and workers to push back  against density. Moreover, the different dimensions of density can reinforce each other: that is, a city with lots of residents and workers will also tend to have more option for shopping, restaurants, and entertainment, which in turn makes the city a more attractive destination for residents and workers. Conversely, when many workers shift to telecommuting and many residents are trying to stay home to the extent possible, the firms that offer shopping, restaurants, and entertainment are going to suffer.  

    Duranton and Puga point out that over time, these kinds of changes and cycles in urban areas are not new. They write: 

    [W]hat will be the long-run consequences of this virus for our densest cities? Pandemics have hit cities the hardest for centuries, and cities have adapted and been shaped by them—from investments in water and sewage systems to prevent cholera, to urban planning to reduce overcrowding and improve air circulation and access to sunlight in response to tuberculosis. Maybe temporary social distancing measures will also leave a permanent footprint on cities—for instance, in the form of more space for pedestrians and bicycles or a gain of outdoor versus indoor leisure environments. But the idea that this pandemic will change cities forever is likely an overstretch. Cities are full of inertia and this crisis has stressed both the costs and benefits of density. Confinement is forcing us to see both the advantages and the great limitations of online meetings relative to the more subtle and unplanned in-person exchanges. It has  made us realize that many tasks are impossible to do from home. At schools and universities, the haphazard transition to online courses may speed up their development, or it may delay it as many students have become frustrated by losing aspects of a full educational experience. For a while, some people may try to avoid dense cities for fear of contagion, but others may be drawn to them seeking work opportunities in difficult times.

    They may turn out to be correct, especially if a trustworthy and effective coronavirus vaccine emerges. Maybe I've just got a case of the 2020 blues today, but I find that I'm less optimistic. It feels to me as if our society is jamming a huge amount of change into a short time. Just in economic terms, for example, there have been conversations about the future of telecommuting, telemedicine, and distance learning for decades--but now we are leaping ahead with all of these changes all at once. I don't expect metropolitan areas to go away, but there may be substantial shifts within a given urban area in what characteristics people desire in their living arrangements, the location of where they work, the mixture of jobs and industries, how people relax, and how often they are willing to mix with a crowd. At present many households and firms are still cobbling together temporary arrangements--or at least arrangements that are intended to be temporary. But some proportion of that temporary is likely to have long-lasting and disruptive effects. 


     -- via my feedly newsfeed