Tuesday, April 7, 2020

Dean Baker: The Length of the Shutdowns Will be Determined by Donald Trump, not Science [feedly]

you got to love Baker's bare-knuckled approach to bullshit

The Length of the Shutdowns Will be Determined by Donald Trump, not Science
https://cepr.net/the-length-of-the-shutdowns-will-be-determined-by-donald-trump-not-science/

Many people are thinking about policy through this crisis as though the country will be largely shut down for many months. This is not going to happen. The length of this shutdown will be determined by Donald Trump, not science, and he is not going to allow a shutdown of many months regardless of what the science says.

We know that Trump was hugely resistant to the shutdown all along. Just over a week ago he was boasting about how we would have full church pews on Easter. The idea that this could means hundreds of thousands of additional infections and tens of thousands of deaths apparently did not enter his head.

Fortunately, some of the public health experts were able to deter his Easter Sunday plans, but it is widely reported that he is anxious to end the shutdown and get back to business as normal. After all, the shutdown is depressing the stock market.

A factor that is likely to push Trump further in this direction is the fact that several European countries are making plans to reopen parts of their economy. Both Austria and Denmark plan to end parts of their shutdown in the next couple of weeks. Undoubtedly Trump will be driven into a rage by the idea that Europe, China, South Korea, and other wealthy countries are back on their feet, while Donald Trump's America is still in shutdown mode.

Of course, these countries have done a far better job testing and controlling the virus, which makes them better situated to reopen their economies (it may still be too soon for them), but Donald Trump doesn't care about such details. The governors will actually make the call on reopening their states, but it is hard to imagine many red state governors resisting the demands from Trump to reopen.

The Democratic governors of states like New York and California may be reluctant to go along, but Trump will have zero qualms about threatening them with denials of medical equipment and other resources if they don't fall in line. Also, the Republicans deliberately starved the blue states of money in the last rescue package. The cost of remaining shut down will mean not having the money to pay the salaries of the police department, the fire department, or for the medical care of people suffering from the coronavirus.

So, when we ask how long the shutdown will last, don't look to the rate of spread of the pandemic or what the epidemiologists say, look to Donald Trump's anger and frustration. We will stay shutdown as long as his fragile ego will allow, and not a day longer.

 

The post The Length of the Shutdowns Will be Determined by Donald Trump, not Science appeared first on Center for Economic and Policy Research


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Dean Baker: Basic Economics for Economic Columnists: A Depression is a Process, not an Event [feedly]

Basic Economics for Economic Columnists: A Depression is a Process, not an Event
https://cepr.net/basic-economics-for-economic-columnists-a-depression-is-a-process-not-an-event/

With the economy going into a shutdown mode for at least month, and possibly quite a bit longer, we're again hearing the cries from elite economics columnists about a Second Great Depression. These are pernicious, not only because they are wrongheaded, but they can be used to justify bad things, like giving hundreds of billions of dollars to the bankers who wrecked the economy with their recklessness during the housing bubble.

The basic and simple error made by the Second Great Depression gang is that they imagine we can be condemned to a prolonged period of high unemployment and slow growth by a single bad event. Their story is that letting the banks fail caused the first Great Depression and that we would have had round two if we let the market work its magic in 2008-09 on Goldman Sachs, Citigroup, and the rest. The uncontrolled bank failures were indeed very bad news for the economy at the start of the Great Depression, and a wave of major bank failures in 2008-09 would undoubtedly have made the initial slump worse in the Great Recession, but neither necessitated a prolonged slump.

What got us out of the Great Depression was the massive spending associated with World War II. There was no economic reason we could not have had this spending in 1931 rather than 1941, except have it focused on building roads, schools, hospitals, and other socially useful projects. We didn't have massive spending in 1931, or 1932, or even during the New Deal, for political reasons, not economic ones.

So let's stop the game-playing. We need good policy right now to keep people whole through a shutdown period and then to get people back to work when we reopen. Ideally, we will also be addressing long-neglected needs, like universal health care, child care, and slowing global warming, but this Second Great Depression stuff is just silly.

The post Basic Economics for Economic Columnists: A Depression is a Process, not an Event appeared first on Center for Economic and Policy Research.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Monday, April 6, 2020

The latest research on the public health and economic costs and benefits of containing the coronavirus pandemic [feedly]

The latest research on the public health and economic costs and benefits of containing the coronavirus pandemic
https://equitablegrowth.org/the-latest-research-on-the-public-health-and-economic-costs-and-benefits-of-containing-the-coronavirus-pandemic/

Scientists around the world are scrambling to find and test anti-viral drugs and a new vaccine for COVID-19, the disease behind the coronavirus pandemic now sweeping the planet. Economists and other social scientists are equally busy attempting to unravel the economic and social consequences of the new coronavirus pandemic. These scholars are looking at a range of issues. Several examine the public health and economic costs and benefits, and the overall efficacy of social distancing. Others explore the links between the epidemiology of the disease and its economic consequences. And others are looking at U.S. historical lessons about the economic impact of the 1918 "Spanish flu" and the political impact of other recent public health scares.

We've selected 10 recently published working papers to highlight. Two of these studies are real-time analyses of social distancing and mobility in Italy and China, respectively, amid the coronavirus pandemic, looking at the public health dynamics in those two countries. Three of the studies step back into U.S. history to offer lessons about the 1918 flu pandemic on subsequent economic growth and about the reaction of voters to Ebola during the 2014 midterm elections. And the other four working papers model the spread of the coronavirus and its social and economic implications.

Let's preview each of them in turn, grouping them together in rough subject categories.

Estimating the economic effects of social distancing and quarantining

"Does Social Distancing Matter?" by Michael Greenstone, director of the Becker Friedman Institute for Economics at the University of Chicago, and Vishan Nigam, a predoctoral fellow at the Energy Policy Institute at the University of Chicago

Greenstone and Nigam project that three months to four months of "moderate social distancing" in the United States starting in late March 2020 would save 1.7 million lives by October 1. The two economists then employ the U.S. government's value of a statistical life to project that "the mortality benefits of social distancing are about $8 trillion or $60,000" per U.S. household; about 90 percent of the "monetized benefits are projected to accrue to people age 50 or older." Their analysis suggests that moderate social distancing over the next seven months would have substantial medium- and long-term economic benefits.

"What Will Be the Economic Impact of COVID-19 in the US? Rough Estimates of Disease Scenarios," by economist Andrew Atkeson at the University of California, Los Angeles

Atkeson engages in another modeling exercise to estimate the spread of COVID-19 over the next 12 months to 18 months based on those who are susceptible to the disease, actively infected with the disease, or either recovered or dead and so no longer contagious. How an epidemic plays out over time is determined by the transition rates between these three states. The working paper applies this model to estimate whether "the fraction of active infections in the population exceeds 1 percent (at which point the health system is forecast to be severely challenged) and 10 percent (which may result in severe staffing shortages for key financial and economic infrastructure) as well as the cumulative burden of the disease over an 18-month horizon." They say their model will allow policymakers to make "quantitative statements regarding the tradeoff between the severity and timing of suppression of the disease through social distancing and the progression of the disease in the population."

"The Macroeconomics of Epidemics," by economists Martin S. Eichenbaum at Northwestern University, Sergio Rebelo at Northwestern's Kellogg School of Management, and Mathias Trabant at the School of Business and Economics at Freie Universität Berlin

In this working paper, Eichenbaum, Rebelo, and Trabant examine "the interaction between economic decisions and epidemics." They model how "people's decisions to cut back on consumption and work reduces the severity of the epidemic, as measured by total deaths." They then explore how these decisions "exacerbate the size of the recession caused by the epidemic." They conclude that "in our benchmark model, when vaccines and treatments don't arrive before the epidemic is over and healthcare capacity is limited, optimal containment policy saves roughly half-a-million lives in the United States."

"Data Gaps and the Policy Response to the Novel Coronavirus," by economist James H. Stock at Harvard University

Stock employs another epidemiological model of contagion to provide economists with a "framework for understanding the effects of social distancing and containment policies on the evolution of contagion and interactions with the economy." Stock explores how different policies that yield the same transmission rate can "have the same health outcomes but can have very different economic costs." His working paper suggests that "one way to frame the economics of shutdown policy" is to find those policies that "trade off the economic cost against the cost of excess lives lost by overwhelming the healthcare system."

"An SEIR Infectious Disease Model with Testing and Conditional Quarantine," by economists David W. Berger at Duke University, Kyle Herkenhoff at the University of Minnesota (and an Equitable Growth grantee), and Simon Mongey at the University of Chicago

These three economists employ another infectious disease epidemiology model to understand how "the role of testing and case-dependent quarantine" can "dampen the economic impact of the coronavirus and reduce peak symptomatic infections," both of which, they say, "are relevant for [understanding] hospital capacity constraints." Their model starts at "a baseline quarantine-only policy that replicates the rate at which individuals are entering quarantine in the United States in March 2020," they explain, then posit that their model can be "used to forecast the effects of public health and economic policies" as the coronavirus continues to spread across the nation.

Real-time research on the coronavirus pandemic in China and Italy

"Human Mobility Restrictions and the Spread of the Novel Coronavirus (2019-nCoV) in China," by Hanming Fang at the Ronald O. Perelman Center for Political Science and Economics, Long Wang at ShanghaiTech University, and Yang Yang at the CUHK Business School at The Chinese University of Hong Kong

In this working paper, these three scholars "quantify the causal impact of human mobility restrictions, particularly the lockdown of the city of Wuhan on January 23, 2020, on the containment and delay of the spread of [COVID-19]." Their working paper seeks "to disentangle the lockdown effect on human mobility reductions from other confounding effects including panic effect, virus effect, and the Spring Festival effect" in Wuhan (referring to the Chinese New Year dates of January 23, to February 2, 2020), finding that "the lockdown of the city of Wuhan on January 23, 2020 contributed significantly to reducing the total infection cases outside of Wuhan." They also find that "that there were substantial undocumented infection cases in the early days of the [COVID-19] outbreak in Wuhan and other cities of Hubei province, but over time, the gap between the officially reported cases and our estimated 'actual' cases narrows significantly." In addition, they find "evidence that enhanced social distancing policies in the 63 Chinese cities outside [of] Hubei province are effective in reducing the impact of population inflows from the epicenter cities in Hubei province on the spread of [COVID-19] in the destination cities elsewhere."

"Compliance with COVID-19 Social-Distancing Measures in Italy: The Role of Expectations and Duration," by Guglielmo Briscese at University of Chicago, Nicola Lacetera at University of Toronto, Maria Macis at Johns Hopkins University's Carey School of Business, and Mirco Tonin at Free University of Bozen-Bolzano

These four scholars examine something different than the rapid spread of the coronavirus in Italy, focusing instead on how Italians' "intentions to comply with the self-isolation restrictions introduced in Italy to mitigate the COVID-19 epidemic respond to the length of their possible extension." Based on survey results, they find that "respondents who are positively surprised by a given hypothetical extension (the extension is shorter than what they expected) are more willing to increase their self-isolation." But they also find that "negative surprises (extensions longer than expected) are associated with a lower willingness to comply." They conclude that their findings "provide insights to public authorities on how to announce lockdown measures and manage people's expectations."

Historical lessons from past epidemics

"The Coronavirus and the Great Influenza Pandemic: Lessons from the 'Spanish Flu' for the Coronavirus's Potential Effects on Mortality and Economic Activity," by economists Robert J. Barro at Harvard University, José F. Ursúa at the fund management firm Dodge & Cox, and Joanna Weng at EverBright, a healthy living online platform focused on Asia

These three economists examine the "mortality and economic contraction during the 1918–1920 Great Influenza Pandemic [to] provide plausible upper bounds for outcomes under …COVID-19." Extrapolating from data for 43 countries, they estimate "flu-related deaths in 1918–1920 of 39 million, 2 percent of world population." This indicates that "150 million deaths" are possible worldwide amid the current coronavirus pandemic. They find that "annual information on flu deaths [between] 1918–1920 and war deaths during WWI imply flu-generated economic declines for [Gross Domestic Product] and consumption in the typical country of 6 [percent] and 8 percent, respectively."

"Pandemics Depress the Economy, Public Health Interventions Do Not: Evidence from the 1918 Flu," by economists Sergio Correia at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Steven Luck at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and Emil Verner at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology's Sloan School of Management

These three economists examine the "geographic variation in mortality during the 1918 Flu Pandemic" in the United States to arrive at the finding that "more exposed areas experience a sharp and persistent decline in economic activity." They estimate that the 1918 pandemic reduced manufacturing output by 18 percent and was driven by both supply- and demand-side shocks to the U.S. economy. They also examined the economic effects of the pandemic across U.S. cities, finding that "cities that intervened earlier and more aggressively do not perform worse and, if anything, grow faster after the pandemic is over." They conclude that the "economic costs and benefits of nonpharmaceutical interventions … not only lower mortality; they also mitigate the adverse economic consequences of a pandemic."

"The Virus of Fear: The Political Impact of Ebola in the U.S.," by economists Filipe R. Campante at Johns Hopkins University's School of Advanced International Studies, Emilio Depetris-Chauvin at Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile, and Ruben Durante at Universitat Pompeu Fabra

This study by three economists and political scientists examines "how fear can affect the behavior of voters and politicians by looking at the Ebola scare that hit the United States a month before the 2014 midterm elections." They say that by "exploiting the timing and location of the four cases diagnosed in the United States, we show that heightened concern about Ebola, as measured by online activity, led to a lower vote share for the Democrats in congressional and gubernatorial elections, as well as lower turnout, despite no evidence of a general anti-incumbent effect (including on President [Barack] Obama's approval ratings)." They further note that "politicians responded to the Ebola scare by mentioning the disease in connection with immigration and terrorism in newsletters and campaign ads," a strategic response that "came only from Republicans, especially those facing competitive races, suggesting a strategic use of the issue in conjunction with topics perceived as favorable to them." Their conclusion about the effects of the Ebola scare in 2014: "Our findings indicate that emotional reactions associated with fear can have a strong electoral impact, that politicians perceive and act strategically in response to this, and that the process is mediated by issues that can be plausibly associated with the specific fear-triggering factor."


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

IMF: An Early View of the Economic Impact of the Pandemic in 5 Charts [feedly]

An Early View of the Economic Impact of the Pandemic in 5 Charts
https://blogs.imf.org/2020/04/06/an-early-view-of-the-economic-impact-of-the-pandemic-in-5-charts/

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Rodrik: Will COVID-19 Remake the World? [feedly]

Will COVID-19 Remake the World?

Dani Rodrik

https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/will-covid19-remake-the-world-by-dani-rodrik-2020-04

No one should expect the pandemic to alter – much less reverse – tendencies that were evident before the crisis. Neoliberalism will continue its slow death, populist autocrats will become even more authoritarian, and the left will continue to struggle to devise a program that appeals to a majority of voters.

CAMBRIDGE – Crises come in two variants: those for which we could not have prepared, because no one had anticipated them, and those for which we should have been prepared, because they were in fact expected. COVID-19 is in the latter category, no matter what US President Donald Trump says to avoid responsibility for the unfolding catastrophe. Even though the coronavirus itself is new and the timing of the current outbreak could not have been predicted, it was well recognized by experts that a pandemic of this type was likely.

Add to Bookmarks

PreviousNext

SARS, MERS, H1N1, Ebola, and other outbreaks had provided ample warning. Fifteen years ago, the World Health Organization revised and upgraded the global framework for responding to outbreaks, trying to fix perceived shortcomings in the global response experienced during the SARS outbreak in 2003.

In 2016, the World Bank launched a Pandemic Emergency Financing Facility to provide assistance to low-income countries in the face of cross-border health crises. Most glaringly, just a few months before COVID-19 emerged in Wuhan, China, a US government report cautioned the Trump administration about the likelihood of a flu pandemic on the scale of the influenza epidemic a hundred years ago, which killed an estimated 50 million people worldwide.

Just like climate change, COVID-19 was a crisis waiting to happen. The response in the United States has been particularly disastrous. Trump downplayed the severity of the crisis for weeks. By the time infections and hospitalizations began to soar, the country found itself severely short of test kits, masks, ventilators, and other medical supplies.

The US did not request test kits made available by the WHO, and failed to produce reliable tests early on. Trump declined to use his authority to requisition medical supplies from private producers, forcing hospitals and state authorities to scramble and compete against one another to secure supplies.

Delays in testing and lockdowns have been costly in Europe as well, with Italy, Spain, France, and the United Kingdom paying a high price. Some countries in East Asia have responded a lot better. South Korea, Singapore, and Hong Kong appear to have controlled the spread of the disease through a combination of testing, tracing, and strict quarantine policies.

Interesting contrasts have emerged within countries as well. In northern Italy, Veneto has done much better than nearby Lombardy, largely owing to more comprehensive testing and earlier imposition of travel restrictions. In the US, the neighboring states of Kentucky and Tennessee reported their first cases of COVID-19 within a day of each other. By the end of March, Kentucky had only a quarter of the number of cases as Tennessee, because the state acted much more quickly to declare a state of emergency and close down public accommodations.

For the most part, though, the crisis has played out in ways that could have been anticipated from the prevailing nature of governance in different countries. Trump's incompetent, bumbling, self-aggrandizing approach to managing the crisis could not have been a surprise, as lethal as it has been. Likewise, Brazil's equally vain and mercurial president, Jair Bolsonaro, has, true to form, continued to downplay the risks.

On the other hand, it should come as no surprise that governments have responded faster and more effectively where they still command significant public trust, such as in South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan.

China's response was typically Chinese: suppression of information about the prevalence of the virus, a high degree of social control, and a massive mobilization of resources once the threat became clear. Turkmenistan has banned the word "coronavirus," as well as the use of masks in public. Hungary's Viktor Orbán has capitalized on the crisis by tightening his grip on power, by disbanding parliament after giving himself emergency powers without time limit.

The crisis seems to have thrown the dominant characteristics of each country's politics into sharper relief. Countries have in effect become exaggerated versions of themselves. This suggests that the crisis may turn out to be less of a watershed in global politics and economics than many have argued. Rather than putting the world on a significantly different trajectory, it is likely to intensify and entrench already-existing trends.

Momentous events such as the current crisis engender their own "confirmation bias": we are likely to see in the COVID-19 debacle an affirmation of our own worldview. And we may perceive incipient signs of a future economic and political order we have long wished for.

So, those who want more government and public goods will have plenty of reason to think the crisis justifies their belief. And those who are skeptical of government and decry its incompetence will also find their prior views confirmed. Those who want more global governance will make the case that a stronger international public-regime health could have reduced the costs of the pandemic. And those who seek stronger nation-states will point to the many ways in which the WHO seem to have mismanaged its response (for example, by taking China's official claims at face value, opposing travel bans, and arguing against masks).

In short, COVID-19 may well not alter – much less reverse – tendencies evident before the crisis. Neoliberalism will continue its slow death. Populist autocrats will become even more authoritarian. Hyper-globalization will remain on the defensive as nation-states reclaim policy space. China and the US will continue on their collision course. And the battle within nation-states among oligarchs, authoritarian populists, and liberal internationalists will intensify, while the left struggles to devise a program that appeals to a majority of voters.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Fwd: New Blog: The Economic Impact of the Pandemic in 5 Charts



---------- Forwarded message ---------
From: International Monetary Fund <content@updates.imf.org>
Date: Mon, Apr 6, 2020 at 9:42 AM
Subject: New Blog: The Economic Impact of the Pandemic in 5 Charts
To: <jcase4218@gmail.com>


The latest IMF analysis on the global economic impact of COVID-19 //

VIEW IN BROWSER

IMF Blog Logo
COVIDBanner


Dear Colleague,

We just published a new blog as part of a special series on the global economic impact of COVID-19. Please find the full text below.

This blog will soon be available in عربي, 中文, Español, Français, 日本語, and Русский.



AN EARLY VIEW OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE PANDEMIC IN 5 CHARTS

By John Bluedorn, Gita Gopinath, Damiano Sandri

The COVID-19 pandemic has pushed the world into a recession. For 2020 it will be worse than the global financial crisis. The economic damage is mounting across all countries, tracking the sharp rise in new infections and containment measures put in place by governments.

China was the first country to experience the full force of the disease, with confirmed active cases at over 60,000 by mid-February. European countries such as Italy, Spain, and France are now in acute phases of the epidemic, followed by the United States where the number of active cases is growing rapidly. In many emerging market and developing economies, the epidemic appears to be just beginning.

Chart1



In Italy, the first country in Europe to be severely hit, the government imposed a national lockdown on March 9 to contain the spread of the virus. As a result, attendance in public places and electricity use have declined dramatically, especially in the northern regions where infection rates have been considerably higher.

Chart2



The economic consequences of the pandemic are already impacting the United States with unprecedented speed and severity. In the last two weeks in March almost 10 million people applied for unemployment benefits. Such a sharp and staggering increase has never been seen before, not even at the peak of the global financial crisis in 2009.

Chart3



Disruptions caused by the virus are starting to ripple through emerging markets. After showing little movement early in the year, the latest indices from purchasing manager surveys (PMIs) are pointing to sharp slowdowns in manufacturing output in many countries, reflecting drops in external demand and growing expectations of declining domestic demand. On a positive note, China is seeing a modest improvement in its PMI after sharp declines early in the year, despite weak external demand.

Chart4



The modest improvement in economic activity in China is reflected also in daily satellite data on nitrogen dioxide concentrations in the local atmosphere—a proxy for industrial and transport activity (but also the density of pollution as a by-product of fossil fuel consumption). After a steep decline from January to February during the acute phase of the pandemic, concentrations have increased as new infections have fallen, allowing China to gradually relax its strict containment measures.

Chart5

 

The recovery in China, albeit limited, is encouraging, suggesting that containment measures can succeed in controlling the epidemic and pave the way for a resumption of economic activity. But there is huge uncertainty about the future path of the pandemic and a resurgence of its spread in China and other countries cannot be ruled out.

To overcome this pandemic, we need a global, coordinated health and economic policy effort. The IMF—in collaboration with other partners—is doing everything it can to ensure rapid support is available to impacted countries through emergency financing, policy advice, and technical assistance.  

We will have more details on the economic impact of the COVID-19 pandemic when the IMF releases its World Economic Outlook on April 14.

John Bluedorn is a Deputy Division Chief on the World Economic Outlook in the IMF's Research Department. Gita Gopinath is the Economic Counsellor and Director of the IMF's Research Department. Damiano Sandri is a Deputy Division Chief in the World Economic Studies Division in the IMF's Research Department.

*****

If you have any comments or feedback on this article, please let me know. For more, read our latest analysis and be sure to explore our COVID-19 policy tracker to stay up-to-date on how 193 economies are responding to the pandemic.

Thank you again for your interest in IMF Blog.

Take good care,

Glenn


Glenn Gottselig
Blog Editor, International Monetary Fund
GGottselig@imf.org

_____

Make a colleague's day: forward this email
Was this newsletter shared with you? Sign up
Update your profile for tailored content
View all IMF newsletters
Unsubscribe from IMF Blog here


This email was sent to jcase4218@gmail.com using GovDelivery Communications Cloud on behalf of: International Monetary Fund · 1900 Pennsylvania Ave NW · Washington, DC · 20431 GovDelivery logo


--

Sunday, April 5, 2020

Trump Administration Scales Back Paid Leave in Coronavirus Relief Law [feedly]

Trump Administration Scales Back Paid Leave in Coronavirus Relief Law
https://www.nytimes.com/2020/04/02/us/politics/coronavirus-paid-leave.html

text only

WASHINGTON — The Trump administration has substantially scaled back paid leave requirements for employers that were created by a new coronavirus relief law, effectively exempting many small businesses in a move that infuriated lawmakers who had fought to expand the benefit.

In guidance issued on Wednesday, the Labor Department said that employers at companies with fewer than 50 workers had broad latitude to decline to offer the 12 weeks of paid leave that the law required for workers whose children were home from school or for child care because of the coronavirus pandemic. The legislation, which provides two weeks of paid sick leave and 12 weeks of paid family leave, and reimburses employers for it with tax credits, already excludes workers at companies with more than 500 employees.

In all, more than 75 percent of American workers are at companies that qualify for exemptions from the law.

Enacted in March, the law said that businesses with fewer than 50 employees could be exempted from providing the leave if it would prevent the business from functioning, leaving it to the Department of Labor to specify what that meant. The department on Wednesday issued its guidelines, giving an expansive definition that allowed small businesses significant leeway not to provide the leave. Under the guidelines, small businesses cannot be exempted from providing sick leave for an employee's own illness.


But companies with fewer than 50 employees could decline to provide paid leave for child care if doing so would "cause the small business to cease operating," if workers' absences would pose "a substantial risk" to the company, or if there were not enough workers "able, willing and qualified" to fill in for the person seeking leave.



Health care providers and first responders, as well as certain federal government employees, can also be denied the paid leave.

Democrats also raised alarm that the new guidelines added requirements that were not in the original law, including that employers could ask employees for certification of the need to take leave, and that employers needed to have work for the employee to do in order for workers to qualify for leave.

Senator Patty Murray of Washington and Representative Rosa DeLauro of Connecticut, both Democrats who pressed for the paid leave expansion, on Wednesday urged Eugene Scalia, the labor secretary, to rescind some guidelines. In a letter, they wrote to Mr. Scalia that the guidelines "violate congressional intent" and "contradict the plain language" of the legislation.

"Given that congressional intent was to respond to the unprecedented nature of this pandemic," the lawmakers wrote, the Labor Department had "the responsibility to provide the maximum flexibility for workers during this crisis — not restricting their leave to when employers grant their consent."



Mr. Scalia said in a statement on Wednesday that the law provided "unprecedented paid leave benefits to American workers affected by the virus, while ensuring that businesses are reimbursed."



The Labor Department guidelines are likely to become part of a broader set of disputes between Congress and the Trump administration over the execution of more than $2 trillion worth of new programs created to respond to the coronavirus crisis, hastily laid out in three sweeping laws enacted over the past month.

The expansion of paid leave provisions was among the most contentious issues as lawmakers and administration officials negotiated legislation last month intended to bolster the social safety net and help families struggling from the reach of the virus. Substantial changes made to the legislation after it passed the House in a post-midnight vote curtailed the scope of the benefits, in part because of the administration's concerns about burdening small businesses.

The legislation ultimately passed the Senate and was signed into law last month, with Senator Mitch McConnell of Kentucky, the majority leader, counseling Republicans "to gag and vote for it anyway."

Democrats have vowed to continue pushing to expand the paid leave provisions in future legislation to prop up an economy that has largely been forced to shutter to slow the spread of the virus. But Republicans have remained reluctant to sign on to such provisions, and Republicans on the House Ways and Means Committee hailed the "greater flexibility" now given to small businesses in a news release on Thursday.

Liberal economists who backed the paid leave program warned that the restrictions would force many workers to make a difficult decision — between caring for their children and keeping their jobs — at a time when fear and uncertainty are running high.

They also raised concerns about the broad exemptions to the program that the Labor Department carved out for health care workers.


"Exempting health care providers and emergency responders threatens our nation's ability to fight back against the coronavirus and makes us all more vulnerable," said Heather Boushey, the president of the Washington Center for Equitable Growth, a think tank focused on inequality and growth. "Our health care workers are the most susceptible to exposure and are in a position to pass it on to other patients. These are the workers who most need to be protected."


 -- via my feedly newsfeed