Monday, November 4, 2019

Dean Baker: Elizabeth Warren's Excellent Opening Gambit on Medicare for All [feedly]

Elizabeth Warren's Excellent Opening Gambit on Medicare for All
http://cepr.net/publications/op-eds-columns/elizabeth-warren-s-excellent-opening-gambit-on-medicare-for-all

Dean Baker
CNN, November 1, 2019

See article on original site

Sens. Elizabeth Warren and Bernie Sanders have set themselves apart from the Democratic presidential field in explicitly advocating Medicare for All proposals. Under their plans, an expanded Medicare system would fully cover everyone in the country. There would be no co-pays, deductibles and premiums — and no private insurance.

Warren has repeatedly been asked how she would pay for this plan. She had resisted saying that she would raise taxes and insisted that costs for the middle-class would go down. On Friday she outlined how this can be done.

The first part of her plan proposes cutting administrative costs. The administrative costs of private insurers are more than 25% of what they pay out in benefits each year. By contrast, the administrative costs of Medicare are less than 3% of what is paid in benefits. The potential savings from getting administrative costs for the whole system down to that of Medicare is close to $3 trillion over the next decade.

The current system imposes large administrative costs on hospitals, doctors' offices, nursing homes and other facilities that need additional staff to deal with complex billing arrangements. These unnecessary administrative expenditures can exceed 20% of total payments. If administrative costs at providers were reduced to Canada's levels (a country with universal coverage), it could save another $2.1 trillion over the next decade.

Warren also proposes large reductions in payments to health care providers. Patients in the US pay drug companies, medical equipment manufacturers, doctors and other providers on average roughly twice as much as in other wealthy countries.

The biggest chunk of her projected savings is on prescription drugs, where she proposes to reduce prices for brand drugs by 70% and generic drugs by 30%. She has likely underestimated the potential savings from these price reductions, since her calculations leave out the roughly $100 billion spent annually on drugs by hospitals, nursing facilities and other providers.

Even with these and other cost savings, Warren projects that the federal government will need another $20 trillion to cover her Medicare for All proposal. She calculates that $9 trillion of this gap will come from the premiums that employers now pay for their workers' health insurance. Employers, she reasons, should not care whether they are paying this money to insurers or the federal government.

This still leaves a gap of $11 trillion, or roughly 5% of GDP. She proposes to fill it with a financial transactions tax, an increase in the corporate income tax, reduced tax avoidance and a wealth tax on the country's very richest people.

Does it all add up?

There are a lot of moving parts here, each of which involves practical as well as political problems. Squeezing payments for pharmaceutical companies (we should do the same for medical equipment companies) will lead to lower spending on research. The government can make this up with additional funding to the National Institutes of Health and other government agencies. Still, the prospect of reduced privately funded research is an issue.

Similarly, lower payments for doctors may lead some to try to practice outside the system. Warren would want to make this difficult, but most likely doctors will have the legal option to practice on their own and charge whatever they want. Some well-connected doctors will likely do this.

There are issues with the planned funding mechanisms. It makes more sense just to charge employers a set percentage of wages rather than base payments on historic insurance premiums. In addition, a wealth tax may prove problematic for a variety of reasons.

However, we should realize this is an opening gambit, not a finished product. The final version of the Affordable Care Act was 2,300 pages when it went to a vote. It is unlikely that a Medicare for All bill will be any shorter.

Warren's proposal is not the final word. But it is an excellent first draft that provides a basis for future debate.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Counting on Class: The Continuing Appeal of Meritocracy [feedly]

Interesting discussion of the "meritocracy" trap. However, there is no other principle, if it could ever be "fairly" defined, around which political and economic negotiations between capital and labor, in both the economic and political realms, is sustainable.


Counting on Class: The Continuing Appeal of Meritocracy
https://workingclassstudies.wordpress.com/2019/11/04/counting-on-class-the-continuing-appeal-of-meritocracy/

Counting on Class: The Continuing Appeal of Meritocracy

Neither faith in nor critiques of the idea of meritocracy is new. Michael Young's famous 1958 book he Rise of Meritocracy argued that class privilege and advantage were likely to be amplified as financial and cultural capital passed across generations in families. Each new generation would benefit from existing structural advantage created by their parents and even grandparents. They might be talented individuals, hardworking and driven to succeed, but they would owe their achievements in part to a myriad of inherited class advantages. Young intended the title of his book as a satire, but for many, it seems to promote the ideal of egalitarian opportunity.

A recent rash of books critically revisit the ideas in Young's now six-decade-old book. In The Class Ceiling: Why it ays to be Privileged, Sam Friendman and Daniel Laurison provide a wonderfully accessible account of contemporary class analysis in the UK, examining the complex ways in which class influences life chances. The authors leaven the numbers with fascinating vignettes from the field showing how successful middle-class professionals are sometimes aware of their own class privilege. As one put it, "I was lucky to have a following wind". The book does not offer a crude demonization of privilege. Instead, the study gets to the heart of how talent and hard work don't sufficiently explain how good jobs get allocated. Often times, as The Class Ceiling shows, it's the lucky breaks that already privileged people enjoy that allow them to achieve yet more success.

Take 'Mark' for example, a successful TV executive in his late thirties. Mark relates to Friedman and Laurison his own 'following wind'. The son of successful educated professionals, he was privately educated before gaining a place at Oxford. While he was at Oxford, Mark's parents paid for him to go on a holiday to New York to do research for his undergraduate dissertation. He stayed in Manhattan for free in an apartment owned by a contact his father had met on the side-lines of a rugby match.  This same contact then provided Mark with an introduction to the television industry. The upside of the anecdote is that Mark is full aware of his privilege and luck.The Class Ceiling is peppered with similar tales of advantage and their mirror image, such as the pairing of Nathan and Jim. Nathan's CV is littered with prestigious roles in TV and film.  He attributes his success to "just working incredibly hard" and "making good decisions" like turning down jobs he didn't believe in.  As he explains, "No job is worth sacrificing yourself for". Jim, by contrast, has decided to leave the acting profession after 'sacrificing' himself and his career by taking the kind of parts Nathan can afford to avoid. Jim's working-class origins still constrain him in his forties.  He struggled so hard to get into the acting profession, but the typecast jobs he has to take ultimately end up damaging his career and lead to offers drying up altogether. Class both constrains and enables after all.

The old formula so loved of politicians and defenders of the status quo that success can be reduced to Talent + Hard Work = Success is well and truly nailed by The Class Ceiling and its intimate stories of success and failure, which show how the safety net allows some to take chances and enjoy opportunities.  What emerges is a profound story of wasted, unrealised talent for those from working-class backgrounds.

This theme is picked up in another important recent book, The Meritocracy Trap by Daniel Markovits. For Markovits, meritocracy isn't working for either the losers or the winners. For middle-class families, the stress involved in 'making it', even for those with privilege, involves constantly monitoring children's progress, pushing them to excel in a bewildering array of extracurricular activities so that they can compete for the jobs or opportunities in the future. The Meritocracy Trap highlights the effect this has on both parents and their off-spring, creating profound and enduring anxiety and mental health issues. I wrote about my own experience of using middle class cultural and economic capital in terms of my own kids in a previous blog. The solution for Markovits involves radically improving education for all social classes to take away incentives to leverage class privilege in schools and colleges.

In The Rise of Meritocracy, Young described precisely the 'following wind' that Friendman and Laurison talk about in The Class Ceiling seven decades later. Sheer talent and hard work wasn't then, and isn't now, going to allow those further down the social scale the chances they need to really succeed. One of my colleagues who researches drugs policy has this neat formulation that politicians 'need to follow the available evidence, not what people would prefer to be true'.  This is also true for commentators who defend the common sense view of meritocracy that talent and hard work will out. In study after study, social scientists repeatedly show that class and other forms of stratification get in the way of merit. Privilege, or the lack of it, shapes individuals' merit, and it can undermine someone with great talent and commitment, or give someone an extra push. So what do we do in the face of the enduring attraction of meritocracy? It helps to keep repeating the inconvenient truth to anyone that will listen. Books like The Class Ceiling and The Meritocracy Trap help enormously by making complex arguments accessible to a wider public, providing the numbers but also giving names and faces to what those the numbers represent.

Tim Strangleman, University of Kent


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Saturday, November 2, 2019

The Impeachable Offense That Democrats Should Stop Ignoring [feedly]

I like adding bread and butter crimes to the impeachment charges..


The Impeachable Offense That Democrats Should Stop Ignoring
http://cepr.net/publications/op-eds-columns/the-impeachable-offense-that-democrats-should-stop-ignoring

Jeff Hauser and Eleanor Eagan
Talking Points Memo, November 1, 2019

See article on original site

For the better part of this year, House Democrats have been consumed by a battle over how best to use their newfound power. One side called for impeachment from the start. The other side insisted that Democrats focus on kitchen table issues like health care. But the choice has always been false; the House can and should do both. In addition to the active impeachment inquiry into Trump's efforts to influence the 2020 election, there should be a second, no less serious impeachment inquiry into Trump's efforts to undermine Obamacare.

The Ukraine scandal merits the sort of no-holds-barred response that House Democrats have been so reluctant to deliver since taking power. Yet, acting as if it's Trump's only impeachable offense risks downplaying the severity of his other, serious misconduct. And fixating on a single story that necessarily involves classified information and international intrigue, rather than corruption of domestic policy matters, is not a savvy political choice.

Trump's attacks on the Affordable Care Act are among his most severe and broadly salient offenses, and his actions are arguably impeachable.

House Speaker Nancy Pelosi (D-CA) has been clear that she considers health care disputes to be best considered outside of the context of impeachment. However, if you look at the Constitution, that assessment quickly falls apart.

Specifically, look to Article II, which states that the president must "take care that the laws be faithfully executed." That's a fancy way of saying that the president has to carry out the laws that Congress writes. How to determine what is faithful execution is a matter of ongoing debate, but it is pretty clear that Trump isn't faithfully administrating the ACA.

In fact, Trump was never coy about his intentions to destroy the law. Mere hours after taking office, he signed an executive order directing members of his administration to undermine Obamacare. Since then, they have happily complied with that order's underlying intent while conveniently ignoring the demand that their actions be "consistent with law." And while the courts have repeatedly affirmed that the president has wide discretionary latitude to decide how to enforce the law, they have not recognized a president's right to effectively repeal laws through executive action.

And that's essentially what Trump is doing.

While the ACA's intent was to "expand coverage in the individual health insurance market," Trump and his administration have openly defied that goal and instead sought to limit healthcare coverage through the ACA exchanges. As former senior White House staffer Steve Bannon bragged, Trump ended payments to health insurance companies subsidizing health care for the poorest Obamacare customers in order to "blow" up the Affordable Care Act.

The Trump administration also decided to cut the ACA's marketing budget by 90%, despite robust evidence from a Center for Medicare Services (CMS) study showing "that paid outreach was responsible for 40 percent of all enrollments." In addition to cutting down on outreach, the administration made it harder for people to find accurate, comprehensive information about the law and its guarantees. The Sunlight Foundation's Web Integrity Project found at least 26 instances in which the administration had censored information about the ACA by removing it from official webpages. No amount of obfuscation could possibly make a convincing case that these actions were undertaken with any goal except to undermine enrollment.

That's not all. In June 2017, Health and Human Services used money that Congress had appropriated for Obamacare outreach efforts to produce and publicize 23 video testimonials "from people who said they had been 'burdened by Obamacare,' including families, health care professionals and small business owners."

Then there's the administration's use of state waivers. While Obamacare made room for state-level innovation through waivers, it set clear parameters. The statute clearly states that the secretary of Health and Human Services may only grant a state waiver request if the state plan "'will provide coverage that is at least as comprehensive as' ACA-compliant coverage." The Trump administration has repeatedly violated this basic restriction by granting state waivers that, for example, impose work requirements on adults seeking medicaid coverage.

Given all of this, Congress has more than adequate grounds to justify an impeachment inquiry to flesh out the already vivid public case that Trump has intentionally sought to undermine, rather than execute, the Affordable Care Act.

We are far from the first to make this case. Last year, four cities and the organization Democracy Forward filed a lawsuit in federal court alleging that Trump's actions constituted a violation of his constitutional duty to "take care." This also wouldn't be the first time that Congress moved to impeach a president on the basis of such a violation. Among the articles of impeachment drawn up and approved against President Andrew Johnson was one accusing him of failing to "take care" to execute the Tenure of Office Act.

There is, therefore, little question that the House has everything it needs to open an impeachment inquiry against Trump for his failure to "take care" in executing the ACA.

They cannot, of course, stop there. In order to build the case for Trump's conviction on this count, they must dig deeper and demonstrate that Trump's actions are indeed motivated by the goal of undermining the law of the land, not just the product of an ideological approach to administering the law within the discretion of the president.

Subpoenas to government officials might reveal even clearer evidence of the direct links between Trump's stated intent to destroy the law and the administration's specific actions that undermined it. A robust investigation might also elicit even more damning evidence by reassuring would-be whistleblowers within the government who believe coming forward is worth the risks. The current impeachment inquiry has already made abundantly clear that a serious investigation with real potential consequences attracts public servants willing to tell the truth. Finally, hearings with witnesses affected by Trump's attacks on the ACA could build public awareness about the severity of Trump's actions. Congress needs to make clear that these abuses are not just reprehensible but likely unconstitutional.

Some may worry that an investigation would be too logistically challenging, and that pursuing such an inquiry might risk taking resources from the Ukraine-focused inquiry, thereby jeopardizing both. But this should not be a concern. As the House Intelligence Committee investigates Trump's actions with regards to Ukraine, the House Judiciary or Energy and Commerce Committees could pursue the line of inquiry we propose.

Democratic lawmakers have spent years talking about the threat Trump and Republicans pose to Americans' healthcare coverage, yet they have been surprisingly reticent to use their power to do anything about it. It is not enough that House Democrats' mere presence in the House majority has stopped Congress from repealing the Affordable Care Act. As should be clear by now, Trump is pursuing repeal through other means, and House Democrats have done nothing to stop him. However, they can still show that their campaign promises to protect voters' healthcare were serious by opening an impeachment inquiry into Trump and his associates' unconstitutional efforts to undermine the ACA.


Jeff Hauser is the director of the Revolving Door Project at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR), which aims to increase scrutiny on executive branch appointments.Eleanor Eagan is a research assistant at the Revolving Door Project.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Fwd: Elizabeth Warren's Medicare for All Plan




via Portside:


 

David Dayan
November 1, 2019
The American Prospect
The deeply detailed proposal includes no new taxes on the middle class. It cuts health care costs and finds other revenues, saving ordinary Americans $11 trillion in premiums and deductibles

, Cheryl Senter/AP Photo

 

Presidential hopeful Elizabeth Warren today released a much-anticipated plan to finance Medicare for All, which she says would require no new taxes on middle-class families. New revenues to fund the single-payer system come mostly from an employer head tax; additional taxes on large corporations, banks, investors, and the wealthy; and military budget cuts. Significant savings to the cost of providing health care, roughly $7 trillion over ten years, also help to reduce the price tag.

The financing does not include Warren's signature wealth tax, though she does add a 3 percent surtax on wealth over $1 billion.

In shifting this financing mix, $11 trillion currently paid by individuals in insurance premiums and deductibles would go back into Americans' pockets. Individuals would still pay the current taxes on Medicare, and whatever taxes fund the state share of health programs, but nothing more. Premium payments and co-pays would be wiped away.

The result is "substantially larger than the largest tax cut in American history," Warren writes in a Medium post on the proposal, framing it as something that significantly lowers overall costs to everyday families. "We can meet these commitments without a tax increase on the middle class—and, in fact, without any increase in income taxes at all."

The detailed plan will test the limits of voter endurance: The Medium post clocks in at over 9,300 words. But the concept is quite simple: Figure out what it costs to pay for health care for the entire country, figure out how much you can reduce that spending, add in health funding that the government already pays for, and then make up the difference.

The whole thing is kind of a ridiculous political exercise, a burden placed upon single-payer advocates that other health care reform plans never have to shoulder. Warren perhaps hopes that she can drill down to such detail to take the issue off the table politically, and challenge other campaigns to step up with similar substance.

But in doing so, Warren's team incorporates a number of other policy preferences outside of health care, including comprehensive immigration reform, banking regulation, initiatives to fight inequality, antitrust enforcement, boosts to unionization, tax compliance, anti-corruption measures, military spending, and more. It really reflects an entire agenda and value set that values working families over the oligarchs currently running roughshod over America.

While there would be enormous challenges to advancing such a complete economic and social transformation, the plan does a meticulous job of answering the nagging "how will you pay for that" question, while attempting to shift the debate by foregrounding the significant benefits of universal coverage, and the personal freedoms it would usher in.

"It gives her a chance to put her stamp on it," Representative Pramila Jayapal (D-WA), author of the Medicare for All bill in the House, told me earlier this week, before the Warren plan came out. And if nothing else, this plan does that.

Here's how it breaks down.

Driving Down Costs

Warren's plan is modeled after the Medicare for All Act, introduced by fellow presidential candidate Bernie Sanders. But that plan doesn't outline exactly how to handle reimbursement of doctors and hospitals, prices for prescription drugs, cuts to administrative costs, and handling of existing state funding of Medicaid. Warren's team tries to fill in these gaps and explicitly identify the savings, relative to an estimated $59 trillion in national health spending under Medicare for All over ten years, contained in an analysis from the Urban Institute.

The campaign leaned heavily on Don Berwick, President Obama's head of the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, the governing body for those federal programs. Berwick has been a single-payer advocate for years since exiting the Obama administration, most recently in a USA Today op-ed. He is as knowledgeable as anyone on how the health care system works, and therefore perfect for analyzing how to realize savings.

If anything, the steps on costs are conservative, considering the U.S. pays nearly twice as much as most industrialized countries on national health expenditures.

The plan envisions dropping administrative spending—the cost of billing and accounting and haggling with different providers—from 12 percent of premiums collected, as with private insurance, to 2.3 percent, which is Medicare's approximate expense. That alone knocks $1.8 trillion off the total cost.

Then, Warren's team goes after high provider prices, easily the biggest driver of health cost inflation. The plan calls for reimbursing physicians and outpatient providers at current Medicare rates, while reimbursing hospitals at 110 percent of Medicare rates. There would be adjustments to that mix, like more reimbursement for primary and preventive care (which could generate its own cost savings), and less for specialty care. Rural and teaching hospitals would get higher reimbursements. And all providers would benefit from simpler administrative processes, lower drug prices, more patients with insurance, and the lifting of uncompensated care.

In addition, Warren proposes ending large geographic cost variances (where hospitals charge wildly different rates for the same treatment), slashing overpayments for rehabilitation and palliative care, and expanding bundled payments that cut down on fee-for-service medicine. All the provider-related savings trim another $2.9 trillion.

On prescription drugs, Warren explicitly promises to reduce brand-name drug prices by 70 percent, and generic prices by 30 percent. She gets there by negotiating all purchases of pharmaceuticals (unlike the 25 high-cost drugs envisioned in House Democrats' H.R. 3) and setting a ceiling of 110 percent of an international index as the highest possible price. If negotiations fail, the plan calls for seizing pharmaceutical patents and licensing them to competitors, or manufacturing them directly, as Warren called for in a bill released late last year. That saves $1.7 trillion, all told, and considering the limited negotiation in H.R. 3 brings an estimated $345 billion in savings, that's a reasonable number.

All told, Warren seeks to slow growth of health care costs over time in line with future expected GDP growth (roughly 3.9 percent). And if the aforementioned options don't get there, Warren suggests using automatic reimbursement reductions or global budgeting, where hospitals get a set amount of money annually as payment. Hitting the growth target, according to the estimates Warren's team provided, would save another $1.1 trillion.

One policy Warren identifies but sets no cost savings for is antitrust enforcement of the health sector. Virtually every part of the health system is incredibly concentrated; research from Cal-Berkeley's Brent Fulton shows that 90 percent of all metropolitan areas have highly concentrated hospital markets, buoyed by 1,667 hospital mergers in the past 20 years. The concentration goes across the chain, from outpatient clinics to group purchasing organizations that raise the cost of medical supplies to pharmacy benefit managers that increase drug costs, and on and on.

Warren has vowed to block all health sector mergers unless they prove that they will maintain or improve care, and rein in anti-competitive behavior sector-wide. But the bean-counters put no savings toward this, despite documented evidence that market power explains much of the rise in health care prices. In fact, a lot of the potential cost savings aren't really accounted for in the Warren plan, like the benefits of widespread preventive care in eliminating the need for more expensive treatments down the road.

That's part of why this whole exercise is somewhat foolish, governed by a Congressional Budget Office whose assumptions are often mercurial and frequently mistaken. Nevertheless, adding up all the savings knocks around $7 trillion off the Urban Institute's $59 trillion, ten-year figure for total health expenditures. In essence, this means that you can cover 24 million more Americans, and ensure that another 63 million aren't underinsured, with the expansion paying for itself through bringing U.S. health care more in line with international norms.

Using the Dollars Already in the System

From that $52 trillion figure, Warren's team then fills in all the existing payments and taxes that the government already puts toward health care. Federal spending through Medicare taxes, as well as Medicare and Medicaid health spending financed by general taxes, comes to a little over $25 trillion over the ten-year period.

Then there's another $6 trillion that reflects the state and local government share of spending for health programs like Medicaid, the Children's Health Insurance Program (CHIP), and coverage for government employees. By using a "maintenance of effort" function that keeps those states paying the same amount for Medicare for All, that lowers the new revenues needed even further. Because overall health spending growth will reduce over time, states will end up spending less through this maintenance of effort provision than they would under current law.

After doing the math, Warren's team projects that new government revenues necessary to finance Medicare for All would come to $20.5 trillion.

Paying the Difference

Warren's biggest mechanism to fill this gap amounts to an employer head tax. The plan estimates that all businesses with over 50 employees—who must provide health care to workers or pay a fee under the Affordable Care Act's employer mandate—will pay around $9 trillion over the next ten years on coverage. Through a complicated formula, the plan creates an employer Medicare contribution that's around 98 percent of the average cost per employee. This means that businesses would save $200 billion in health care costs over ten years.

Part-time employees would count toward that per capita total, along with those workers seen as independent contractors today, who would fall under Warren's expanded definition of an employee. Small businesses under 50 employees would be exempt from the head tax unless they're providing employee health care today. Pass-through businesses like law firms and private equity firms would have to pay the head tax.

In an ingenious twist, employers operating under a collective-bargaining agreement would have their head tax reduced, if they pass any savings under that to workers in wages or benefits. In other words, the plan would incentivize collective bargaining, not just for workers, but for employers as well.

In all, this estimates revenues of $8.8 trillion, over 40 percent of the way to the total. If it doesn't get there, Warren would trigger a supplemental tax on companies with high executive salaries and large amounts of stock buybacks. Repeatedly in this plan, she discourages behavior she wants to get rid of, and vice versa.

The next bucket of money may be a little tricky. Because workers will not contribute to health insurance through their paycheck, Warren's team presumes they will take home that pay. That additional $3.7 trillion in workers' pockets would constitute newly taxable income, and therefore another $1.15 trillion in tax revenue.

This assumes that employers won't assess a "fair share fee" to have workers pay for health care, which you could envision happening. A senior Warren aide doubted this would take place, because employers make out better under the plan than what they contribute today. But that's not true for large corporations and multinationals, as we'll see. The question of whether workers will realize higher take-home pay after Medicare for All is a critical one, and not a complete slam dunk in my view.

It is true that workers won't have to bother with health savings accounts to shelter money for medical costs, or tax deductions for medical expenses. That saves another $250 billion.

The plan gets another $2.3 trillion by collecting what is already owed to the government. Warren goes about reducing the gap between the taxes people are supposed to pay and what they actually do by adding significant enforcement funding, expanding tax compliance measures, and redirecting audits to high-income earners.

Then there are targeted taxes on the financial sector: a 0.1 percent financial transaction tax on stocks, bonds, and derivatives, and a "systemic risk" fee on banks with more than $50 billion in assets. Ironically, the latter fee was part of Dodd-Frank until Scott Brown, whom Warren replaced in the Senate, forced the fee out as a condition for his vote. These two taxes reap another $900 billion.

Warren would close the expensing loophole, which allows businesses to realize the full cost of equipment investments up front. She would increase the minimum tax on multinationals that park earnings abroad to 35 percent, while prohibiting deferring those tax payments. She would put a tax on the domestic sales of foreign firms as well. That adds $2.9 trillion.

There's an expansion of the "two cent" wealth tax through a surcharge of an additional three cents on wealth over $1 billion. Warren would also include a "mark-to-market" system of annually collecting capital gains taxes based on gains from that year, rather than only collecting capital gains on a sale. Senator Ron Wyden (D-OR) has proposed this change. A total of $3 trillion comes from these two changes.

Another $800 billion comes from eliminating an egregious slush fund for military spending called Overseas Contingency Operations, or OCO. This was supposed to be a short-term fund to finance war fighting, but has become a way to increase military budgets magically without counting the spending.

Finally, Warren applies the increased revenues from comprehensive immigration reform, around $400 billion according to an earlier estimate of an immigration bill from 2013. That revenue comes from taking the undocumented out of the shadows and giving them a path to citizenship, whereupon they pay federal taxes. To actually use such a pay-for, you would have to put the immigration bill into the Medicare for All bill; either one of them alone would be a heavy lift to pass, let alone both together.

All told, this $11 trillion in new revenue would still put America in the middle of the pack among developed nations in terms of taxation.

The Politics

In theory, that all costs out, according to top economists like MIT's Simon Johnson, former Obama Council of Economic Advisers member Betsey Stevenson, and Moody's Mark Zandi. The financing pays for a universal single-payer system without new taxes on the middle class. Individuals would pay for health care, of course, just as they do now: through dedicated Medicare taxes, and state and federal taxes that get put toward health care programs. But that would be it.

More than anything, this comprehensive assessment allows Warren to pivot. Other candidates can quibble with her numbers, but she starts from the base of giving Americans back $11 trillion in individual premium and deductible payments. She can now assert the principles she leads her Medium post with, that nobody should go bankrupt in America from high-cost health care, that nobody should endure the hassle of determining in-network doctors and what treatments insurers will cover, that nobody should die from lack of access. She can lead on values instead of costs and financing.

"Every candidate who opposes my long-term goal of Medicare for All should put forward their own plan to cover everyone, without costing the country anything more in health care spending, and while putting $11 trillion back in the pockets of the American people," Warren writes, turning the tables on her opponents. "If they are unwilling to do that, they should concede that they think it's more important to protect the eye-popping profits of private insurers and drug companies and the immense fortunes of the top 1% and giant corporations."

I could see hardcore Sanders supporters cherry-picking the words "long-term goal" and claiming that Warren is not committed to getting Medicare for All done. But this plan is so wrapped up with her other concerns, and so in line with her populist message, that I think it will pass the test for most single-payer fans. And it allows her to go on offense against Joe Biden, Pete Buttigieg, and others, asking them why they don't cover everyone, why they don't cut costs, why they don't want to end the horror of medical bankruptcies and unnecessary deaths.

"We need plans, not slogans," Warren concludes.

Read the original article at Prospect.org.
Used with the permission. © The American Prospect, Prospect.org, 2019. All rights reserved. 
Read the original article at Prospect.org.
Used with the permission. The American Prospect, Prospect.org, 2019. All rights reserved.

 Support the American ProspectClick here to support the Prospect's brand of independent impact journalism

 

 
 

Interpret the world and change it

 
 
 

Privacy Policy

To unsubscribe, click here.



--

Friday, November 1, 2019

Jared Bernstein: October jobs report: Robust job growth minus wage pressure equals NOT-full-employment. [feedly]

October jobs report: Robust job growth minus wage pressure equals NOT-full-employment.
http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/october-jobs-report-robust-job-growth-minus-wage-pressure-equals-not-full-employment/

Payrolls rose 128,000 last month, well above expectations for 85K, and job gains in the prior two months were revised up by 95,000 (a sizable upward revision). Also, the October gain of 128K was dampened by the absence of about 50,000 striking workers at General Motors who are now back at work as the strike ended. In other words, despite slowing global growth, political uncertainty, weakening trade flows hit by the trade war, the U.S. job creation machine remains in high gear.

What's missing–and it is a serious omission–is wage growth. Yes, wages are rising at a decent yearly clip of around 3% and importantly, they're beating inflation which is running below 2%. But if anything, wage growth, at least for the series in this report, has decelerated in recent months (see figures below; another series show flattening; none show acceleration). This, along with weak inflation data, strongly suggests the labor market is not at full employment. If it were–if labor demand was strong enough to trigger clear supply constraints–we'd see be seeing considerably more wage pressure.

The unemployment rate ticked up to 3.6% last month, but for good reasons: more workers entering the workforce, as the labor force rate also ticked up slightly. At 63.3%, it's the highest it has been since August 2013. More important, since the overall rate includes elderly people leaving the job market for retirement, the closely watched prime-age employment rate rose to 80.3%, climbing back for the first time to its 2007 peak. This is evidence that persistent, high-pressure labor market is pulling people in, and another indicator that labor market capacity is greater than many believed to be the case earlier in the recovery.

Another indicator of the benefits of running a high-pressure job market is seen in the African American unemployment rate, which at 5.4%, hit an all-time low last month with data going back to 1972. Due in part to systemic racism, black unemployment rates–at all education levels–are higher than those of whites. Pushing the other way, however, is the fact that minority workers often respond more strongly than whites to cyclical gains of the type we've been seeing of late. It is thus notable that over the past three months (August, September, and October) the black/white unemployment gap has been the lowest on record. Since 1972, the average gap (black unemp – white unemp) has been about 6 percentage points. Over the last three months, it was 2.1, 2.3, and 2.2 respectively.

Readers know that we use our monthly smoother to boost the signal-to-noise ratio in the payroll data by taking averages of monthly gains over 3, 6, and 12 month periods. This month's smoother has an extra set of bars, as we've (where "we" means the remarkably efficient Kathleen Bryant) added 50K back into the payroll gains to account for the strike. Doing so reveals a quite strong pace of job gains over the past 3 months of 192K. The 12-month average yields a longer-run trend of around 180K, also a strong number, and easily big enough to keep the unemployment rate below 4 percent for the near future.

So where's the wage pressure? The next two figures show wage growth clearly accelerated as the job market tightened, then stalled in recent months. I'm sure some commentators will make the point that as unemployment has bottom out in the mid-3's (i.e., it's not been falling further), we shouldn't expect wage acceleration. (Technically, this argues wages are on the wage-Phillips-curve line.) It's a fair point, but it also implies that employers are not facing pressures to further bid up pay to get and hold onto the workers they need to meet the demand for the goods and services they're selling. And absent these pressures, along with a) weak inflation data and b) the higher participation figures cited above, the fact remains that while the U.S. job market is going strong, it's not yet at full employment.

 


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Chile: The Poster Boy of Neoliberalism who Fell from Grace [feedly]

I am allergic to "neoliberalism" rants (for most, just a shamefaced way ranting against capitalism). But Branko Milanovic rundown on Chile is on the money, and I KNOW what HE means by the term, since he does the courtesy of spelling it out.  I call Milanovic, the Eeyore of economics. :)

Chile: The Poster Boy of Neoliberalism who Fell from Grace
https://www.globalpolicyjournal.com/blog/30/10/2019/chile-poster-boy-neoliberalism-who-fell-grace

Branko Milanovic explores the meaning of recent protests in Chile.
 
It is not common for an OECD county to shoot and kill 16 people in two days of socially motivated riots. (Perhaps only Turkey, in its unending wars against the Kurdish guerilla, comes close to that level of  violence.) This is however what Chilean government, the poster child of neoliberalism and transition to democracy, did last week in the beginning of protests that do not show the signs of subsiding despite cosmetic reforms proposed by President Sebastian Piñera.
 
The fall from grace of Chile is symptomatic of worldwide trends that reveal the damages caused by neoliberal policies over the past thirty years, from privatizations in Eastern Europe and Russia to the global financial crisis to the Euro-related austerity. Chile was held, not the least thanks to favorable press that it enjoyed, as an exemplar of success. Harsh policies introduced after the overthrow of Salvador Allende in 1973, and the murderous spree that ensued afterwards, have been softened by the transition to democracy but their essential features were preserved. Chile indeed had a remarkably good record of growth, and while in the 1960-70s it was in the middle of the Latin American league by GDP per capita, it is now the richest Latin American country. It was of course helped too by high prices for its main export commodity, copper, but the success in growth is incontestable. Chile was "rewarded" by the membership in the OECD, a club of the rich nations, the first South American country to accede to it.
 
Where the country failed is in its social policies which somewhat bizarrely were considered by many to have been successful too. In the 1980s-90s, the World Bank hailed Chilean "flexible" labor market policies which consisted of breaking up the unions and imposing a model of branch-level negotiations between employers and workers rather than allowing an overall umbrella union organization to negotiate for all workers. It was even more bizarrely used by the World Bank as a model of transparency and good governance, something that the transition countries in Eastern Europe should have presumably copied from Chile. The brother of the current Chilean president, scions of one of the richest families in Chile, became famous for introducing, as Minister of Labor and Social Security under Pinochet, a funded system of pensions where employees make compulsory contributions from their wages into one of several pension funds, and after retirement receive pensions based on investment performance of such funds. Old-age pensions thus became a part of  roulette capitalism. But In the process, the pension funds, charging often exorbitant fees, and their managers became rich. José Piñera had tried to "sell" this model to Yeltsin's Russia and to George Bush's United States, but, despite the strong (and quite understandable) support of the financial communities in both countries, he failed. Nowadays, most Chilean pensioners receive $200-$300 per month in a country whose price level (according to International Comparison Project, a worldwide UN- and World Bank-led project to compare price levels around the world) is about 80% of that of the United States.
 
While Chile leads Latin America in GDP per capita, it also leads it terms of inequality. In 2015, its level of income inequality was higher than in any other Latin American country except for Colombia and Honduras. It exceeded even Brazil's proverbially high inequality. The bottom 5% of the Chilean population have an income level that is about the same as that of the bottom 5% in Mongolia. The top 2% enjoy the income level equivalent to that of the top 2% in Germany. Dortmund and poor suburbs of Ulan Bataar were thus brought together.
 
Chilean income distribution is extremely unequal. But even more so is its wealth distribution. There, Chile is an outlier even compared to the rest of Latin America. According to the Forbes' 2014 data on world billionaires, the combined wealth of Chilean billionaires' (there were twelve of them) was equal to 25% of Chilean GDP. The next Latin American countries with highest wealth concentrations are  Mexico and Peru where the wealth share of billionaires is about half (13 percent of GDP) of Chile's. But even better: Chile is the country where billionaires' share, in terms of GDP, is the highest in the world (if we exclude countries like Lebanon and Cyprus where many foreign billionaires simply "park" their wealth for tax reasons). The wealth of Chile's billionaires, compared to their country's GDP, exceeds even that of Russians.
 
Chile.png

 

Such extraordinary inequality of wealth and income, combined with full marketization of many social services (water, electricity etc.), and pensions that depend on the vagaries of the stock market have long been "hidden" from foreign observers by Chile's success in raising its GDP per capita.  But the recent protests show that the latter is not enough. Growth is indispensable for economic success and reduction in poverty. But if there Is no social justice and minimum of social cohesion, the effects of growth will dissolve in grief, demonstrations, and yes, in the shooting of people. 


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Mark Thoma's Links (10/31/19) [feedly]

Good summaries and links  to the latest posts.

Links (10/31/19)
https://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2019/10/links-103119.html

  • Manufacturing Ain't Great Again. Why? - Paul Krugman  
    When Donald Trump promised to Make America Great Again, his slogan meant different things to different people. For many supporters it meant restoring the political and social dominance of white people, white men in particular. For others, however, it meant restoring the kind of economy we had a generation or two ago, which offered lots of manly jobs for manly men: farmers, coal miners, manufacturing workers. So it may matter a lot, politically, that Trump has utterly failed to deliver on that front — and that workers are noticing. Now, many of Trump's economic promises were obvious nonsense. The hollowing out of coal country reflected new technologies, like mountaintop removal, which require few workers, plus competition from other energy sources, especially natural gas but increasingly wind and solar power. Coal jobs aren't coming back, no matter how dirty Trump lets the air get.
  • Stop Inflating the Inflation Threat - J. Bradford DeLong 
    Given the scale and severity of inflation in America in the 1970s, it is understandable that US monetary policymakers developed a deep-seated fear of it. But, nearly a half-century later, the conditions that justified such worries no longer apply, and it is past time that we stopped denying what the data are telling us.
  • How to Tax Our Way Back to Justice - Saez and Zucman 
    It is absurd that the working class is now paying higher tax rates than the richest people in America.
  • It's Time to Go - Dave Giles
    When I released my first post on the blog on 20th. Febuary 2011 I really wasn't sure what to expect! After all, I was aiming to reach a somewhat niche audience. Well, 949 posts and 7.4 million page-hits later, this blog has greatly exceeded my wildest expectations. However, I'm now retired and I turned 70 three months ago. I've decided to call it quits, and this is my final post. I'd rather make a definite decision about this than have the blog just fizzle into nothingness. For now, the Econometrics Beat blog will remain visible, but it will be closed for further comments and questions.
  • Prospects for Inflation in a High Pressure Economy: Is the Phillips Curve Dead or Is It Just Hibernating? - Brad DeLong 
    I have some disagreements with this by the smart Sufi, Mishkin, and Hooper: the evidence for "significant nonlinearity" in the Phillips Curve is that the curve flattens when inflation is low, not that it steepens when labor slack is low. There is simply no "strong evidence" of significant steepening with low labor slack. Yes, you can find specifications with a t-statistic of 2 in which this is the case, but you have to work hard to find such specifications, and your results are fragile. The fact is that in the United States between 1957 and 1988—the first half of the last 60 years—the slope of the simplest-possible adaptive-expectations Phillips Curve was -0.54: each one-percentage point fall in unemployment below the estimated natural rate boosted inflation in the subsequent year by 0.54%-points above its contemporary value. Since 1988—in the second half of the past 60 years—the slope of this simplest-possible Phillips curve has been effectively zero: the estimated regression coefficient has been not -0.54 but only -0.03. The most important observations driving the estimated negative slope of the Phillips Curve in the first half of the past sixty years were 1966, 1973, and 1974—inflation jumping up in times of relatively-low unemployment—and 1975, 1981, and 1982—inflation falling in times of relatively-high unemployment. The most important observations driving the estimated zero slope of the Phillips Curve in the second half of the past sixty years have been 2009-2014: the failure of inflation to fall as the economy took its Great-Recession excursion to a high-unemployment labor market with enormous slack. Yes, if we had analogues of (a) two presidents, Johnson and Nixon, desperate for a persistent high-pressure economy; (b) a Federal Reserve chair like Arthur Burns eager to accommodate presidential demands; (c) the rise of a global monopoly in the economy's key input able to deliver mammoth supply shocks; and (d) a decade of bad luck; then we might see a return to inflation as it was in the (pre-Iran crisis) early and mid-1970s. But is that really the tail risk we should be focused monomaniacally on? And how is it, exactly, that "the difference between national and city/state results in recent decades can be explained by the success that monetary policy has had in quelling inflation and anchoring inflation expectations since the 1980s"? Neither of those two should affect the estimated coefficient. Much more likely is simply that—at the national level and at the city/state level—the Phillips Curve becomes flat when inflation becomes low:
  • Debt, Doomsayers and Double Standards - Paul Krugman 
    Selective deficit hysteria has done immense damage.
  • Fed Attempts To Conclude Their Mid-Cycle Adjustment - Tim Duy
    After spending much of the year battling the forces of uncertainty weighing on the economy, the Fed declared victory today. Absent a fresh deterioration in the economic outlook, Fed Chair Jerome Powell and his colleagues believe they are done cutting rates with this month's policy move. Expect an extended policy pause; the Fed is neither interested in easing policy further given their outlook nor in soon raising rates back up given continued below-target inflation.
  • Fall 2019 Journal of Economic Perspectives Available Online - Tim Taylor 
    I'll start with the Table of Contents for the just-released Fall 2019 issue, which in the Taylor household is known as issue #130. Below that are abstracts and direct links for all of the papers. I will probably blog more specifically about some of the papers in the next week or two, as well.
  • Does a wealth tax discourage risky investments? – Digitopoly 
    The other day I wrote about the potential impact of a wealth tax. In so doing, I wrote: "we can all agree that the wealth tax likely deters risk-free saving." This was a paraphrase of a claim made by Larry Summers who then went on to say that it was unknown whether a wealth tax would encourage or discourage risky investment. But I did wonder what the impact of a wealth tax would be on various types of investments and in examining this I realized that the claim was incorrect. In fact, a wealth tax is unlikely to have any change on the risk profile of investments in contrast to an income (or even consumption tax) that will. I discovered later that this was a known result being contained in a paper from Joe Stiglitz (QJE, 1969).
  • Will Libra Be Stillborn? - Barry Eichengreen
    Where the problem for economies and financial services is lack of competition, residents of developing countries need to look to their own regulators and politicians. The remedy for their woes is not going to come from Mark Zuckerberg.
  • Children of Poor Immigrants Rise, Regardless of Where They Come From - The New York Times 
    A pattern that has persisted for a century: They tend to outperform children of similarly poor native-born Americans.
  • The tempos of capitalism - Understanding Society 
    I've been interested in the economic history of capitalism since the 1970s, and there are a few titles that stand out in my memory. There were the Marxist and neo-Marxist economic historians (Marx's Capital, E.P. Thompson, Eric Hobsbawm, Rodney Hilton, Robert Brenner, Charles Sabel); the debate over the nature of the industrial revolution (Deane and Cole, NFR Crafts, RM Hartwell, EL Jones); and volumes of the Cambridge Economic History of Europe. The history of British capitalism poses important questions for social theory: is there such a thing as "capitalism", or are there many capitalisms? What are the features of the capitalist social order that are most fundamental to its functioning and dynamics of development? Is Marx's intellectual construction of the "capitalist mode of production" a useful one? And does capitalism have a logic or tendency of development, as Marx believed, or is its history fundamentally contingent and path-dependent? Putting the point in concrete terms, was there a probable path of development from the "so-called primitive accumulation" to the establishment of factory production and urbanization to the extension of capitalist property relations throughout much of the world?
  • The Way We Measure the Economy Obscures What Is Really Going On - Heather Boushey 
    By looking mainly at the big picture, we are missing the reality of inequality — and a chance to level the playing field.
  • Audits as Evidence: Experiments, Ensembles, and Enforcement - Brad DeLong 
    This is absolutely brilliant, and quite surprising to me. I had imagined that most of discrimination in the aggregate was the result of a thumb placed lightly on the scale over and over and over again. Here Pat and Chris present evidence that, at least in employment, it is very different: that a relatively small proportion of employers really really discriminate massively, and that most follow race-neutral procedures and strategies:
  • Study analyzed tax treaties to assess effect of offshoring on domestic employment - EurekAlert 
    The practice of offshoring--moving some of a company's manufacturing or services overseas to take advantage of lower costs--is on the rise and is a source of ongoing debate. A new study identified a way to determine how U.S. multinational firms' decisions about offshoring affect domestic employment. The study found that, on average, when U.S. multinationals increase employment in their foreign affiliates, they also modestly increase employment in the United States--albeit with substantial dislocation and reallocation of workers. The study was conducted by researchers at Carnegie Mellon University, Georgetown University, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. It is published in The Review of Economics and Statistics

 -- via my feedly newsfeed