https://www.cbpp.org/research/full-employment/helping-manufacturing-intensive-communities-what-works
This report was commissioned by the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities' Full Employment Project. Views expressed within the report do not necessarily reflect the views of the Center.
Since 2000, U.S. manufacturing jobs have declined by more than one-third.[2] As a result, communities with above-average shares of manufacturing have typically performed much worse than the average community in the United States.
Figure 1 shows the performance of the local labor markets in the United States that are the most manufacturing intensive.[3] These communities account for about one-quarter of U.S. jobs and population. But these communities suffered almost half of the post-2000 job loss in U.S. manufacturing. Their overall job trends have been much worse than the U.S. average.
These manufacturing-intensive communities, compared to the entire United States, have a job-growth gap of over 11 percentage points (a 2.7 percent loss of total private jobs in the manufacturing-intensive communities, versus an 8.5 percent gain in the entire United States). At least three-fifths of this job-growth gap is explained by these areas' greater manufacturing share.[4]
Can anything be done to help manufacturing-intensive communities? What local policies offer cost-effective ways to spur local job growth? Can these communities succeed by reviving manufacturing? This paper seeks to answer these questions.[5]
The short answers are these:
- Success for manufacturing-intensive communities is possible.
- We know what policies make sense to increase such communities' job growth.
- Such policies can boost local manufacturing.
Since 2007, a significant minority of manufacturing-intensive communities have had above-average job growth. Of this successful group, about half have done much better than the United States in manufacturing job growth.
My analysis of these successful communities shows some commonalities in their economic development approaches. My analysis identifies three cost-effective development strategies:
- Expand customized services to small and medium-sized manufacturers.Manufacturing can be cost-effectively promoted by manufacturing extension services and customized job training. Manufacturing extension services provide individual firms with lower-cost access to high-quality advice on improving competitiveness. Customized job-training programs provide worker training specific to the firm's skill needs.
- Invest in infrastructure and services that make the community's land better for business development. Job growth can be cost-effectively promoted by improving services in distressed neighborhoods, cleaning up brownfields, and investing in transportation infrastructure.
- Increase public spending on services that increase local workers' job skills. Better skills for local workers help attract and grow higher-wage jobs. Adult skills can be improved by programs from birth onward. Effective skills development programs include the following: high-quality child care, high-quality preschool, K-12 education, college scholarships, and adult job training.
Success Is Possible for Manufacturing-Intensive Communities
To identify determinants of success in manufacturing-intensive communities, my analysis focuses on local labor markets whose populations exceed 200,000. I do not consider smaller communities, whose success could be due to one plant opening, and are unlikely to yield generalizable lessons.
I identified 105 local labor markets that exceed 200,000 in population and are manufacturing-intensive. Out of those 105 areas, I categorized 22 areas as "successful" based on their meeting two criteria: 1) 2007-2015 private job growth greater than the U.S. average and 2) 2000-2015 private job growth that was positive.[6] I categorized the other 83 areas as "unsuccessful." Figure 2 compares private job growth from 2007 to 2015 in the United States, the unsuccessful 83 areas, and the successful 22 areas.
From 2007 to 2015, U.S. manufacturing jobs declined by 13.8 percent. The successful 22 areas had a manufacturing job share almost 50 percent greater than the U.S. average.[7] Yet despite U.S. manufacturing trends that were adverse, these 22 communities had job growth almost 2 percentage points greater than the United States: 4.7 percent for these 22 manufacturing-intensive areas, versus 2.8 percent average job growth for the United States as a whole. How did they do it?
Out of the 22 areas, half succeeded despite large manufacturing job losses. The other half succeeded in part by doing better than the United States in manufacturing.
Seven areas did worse than the U.S. in manufacturing job growth (meaning they lost more than 13.8 percent in manufacturing jobs). But six other areas had manufacturing job growth. Another five areas, although they lost manufacturing jobs, did at least 10 percentage points better than the United States (that is, they had manufacturing losses less severe than −3.8 percent). Therefore, 11 out of the 22 successful manufacturing-intensive areas either grew manufacturing jobs or had only modest manufacturing job loss.
Consider the four successful areas whose population exceeded 1 million: 1) Silicon Valley in California; 2) Charlotte, North Carolina; 3) Grand Rapids, Michigan; and 4) the Lehigh Valley in Pennsylvania. Silicon Valley and Charlotte succeeded despite doing poorly in manufacturing: Silicon Valley suffered a manufacturing job loss of 35.5 percent, and Charlotte had a manufacturing job loss of 16.2 percent.
The Grand Rapids area and the Lehigh Valley succeeded in part because they did better than the United States in manufacturing. From 2007 to 2015, Grand Rapids had 4.9 percent manufacturing job growth. The Lehigh Valley lost manufacturing jobs, but only by 0.4 percent.
Consider Grand Rapids. Figure 3 shows Grand Rapids' manufacturing job growth since 1990. To compare this performance with that of the United States, both the United States and Grand Rapids are indexed to a value of 100 in 1990.
Grand Rapids did not escape the large job declines in manufacturing in the United States from 2000 until 2009. But during periods when U.S. manufacturing jobs were holding steady, Grand Rapids showed healthy manufacturing job growth. By 2016, manufacturing jobs in Grand Rapids were over 50 percent greater than if Grand Rapids had followed post-1990 U.S. trends.[8]
What Explains the Success of Certain Manufacturing-Intensive Communities?
How do we account for successful manufacturing-intensive communities? My analysis identified policy variables that were correlated with 2007-2015 private-sector job growth in these 105 larger manufacturing-intensive local labor markets.[9]
I find no evidence that job growth in these areas is significantly spurred by cutting business taxes or increasing business tax incentives. The estimates are precise enough to rule out the possibility that such lower business costs could have large growth effects per dollar of cost reduction.
In contrast, customized business services boost job growth in manufacturing-intensive communities. For example, communities experience stronger job growth in states that invest more in customized job training programs, all else being the same.[10] Customized training programs provide free or reduced-cost training, typically delivered by community colleges, that meets the specific skill needs of an individual firm seeking to hire new workers or upgrade its existing workforce. Total state government investment in customized training is around $600 million per year (Hollenbeck 2013).
Another customized business service that works is manufacturing extension services. Manufacturing extension services provide small and medium-sized manufacturers with consulting advice on improving technology, product design, and marketing. Advice is provided by the manufacturing extension office, in cooperation with university and private-sector experts. Each U.S. state has at least one manufacturing extension office, which is funded by federal, state, and local governments and by client fees. Total funding for manufacturing extension is around $400 million per year, with one-half to two-thirds from governments.[11]
My analysis measures an area's intensity of manufacturing extension services by the job creation or retention due to manufacturing extension, as reported in client surveys.[12] Reported extension-induced job creation or retention is a significant predictor of an area's overall job growth, holding constant other growth determinants.[13]
Finally, a community's job growth is significantly affected by the skills of its workforce. Manufacturing-intensive areas with more workers with a college degree had higher job growth, all else being the same.[14]
The estimated effects of customized business services, or of job skills, are large enough to be economically significant. For example, consider the effects of changing these variables from the values they have in an area with a relatively low level of these variables, to the values in an area with a relatively high level of these variables.[15] Table 1 shows such effects.
If a community moves from a relatively low to high level in providing customized business services, job growth increases by 3.6 percentage points (= 1.93 percent + 1.67 percent). The percentage of workers who are college educated is less immediately affected by policy, but a community's higher ranking on this variable would increase growth by over 6 percentage points.
TABLE 1 | |
---|---|
Effect on Private-Sector Job Growth, 2007–2015, in Manufacturing-Intensive Areas, of Changing Three Policy Variables from Low to High Values (%) | |
Customized job-training spending | 1.93 |
Manufacturing-extension-reported job creation or retention | 1.67 |
Percentage of workforce college-educated | 6.31 |
But this is one study. What does the overall research literature say?
Cost-Effectiveness of Policies to Increase Local Job Growth
Much evidence exists on the cost-effectiveness of promoting local job growth through different policies. This research suggests that business tax cuts and incentives are relatively expensive. More cost-effective are two other strategies: 1) customized business services and 2) services and infrastructure to increase the attractiveness of land for business investment.
In measuring cost-effectiveness, we should account for how long jobs last, and when costs are incurred. This paper compares policies by the ratio of the policy's costs to the number of "job-years" the policy creates. One job-year is a job that lasts one year.[16]
A policy's costs per job-year can be compared with local benefits. Local benefits of a job are less than the job's pay. In the long run, 15 percent of new local jobs lead to additional job opportunities for the local non-employed; the other 85 percent lead to jobs for in-migrants.[17] Because average U.S. annual earnings are about $60,000, the benefits of local job creation due to increased local earnings from higher employment rates are around $9,000 per job-year. Other local benefits and costs could be added. Jobs may increase local wages, benefiting workers and hurting businesses. Some costs may occur from residents' reduced non-work time. Growth increases housing prices, which benefits property owners and hurts renters. Growth also increases state and local tax revenue, but in-migration drives up public service needs. Local benefits plausibly total $5,000 to $20,000 per job-year.[18]
For different local policies, Figure 4 presents annual costs per job-year created. These estimated costs per job come from many rigorous studies.[19]
Business tax cuts have a cost per job-year created that is quite high, costing about $46,600.[20] Because other costs differ greatly across local areas (e.g., worker productivity), it takes a large business tax cut to tip business location decisions.
Business tax incentives are also expensive, at an estimated $16,600 per job-year.[21] Incentive costs are lower than business tax cuts because incentives can be targeted at "export-base" firms, which are firms that sell goods and services outside the region, such as manufacturers. Export-base sales bring new dollars into a local economy. Other local jobs are created as the export-base firm buys from local suppliers and as its workers buy from local retailers.
In contrast, non-export-base firms sell goods and services to local customers. Expanded sales at one non-export-base firm takes sales away from local competitors. This reduces job-creation effects of policies that include non-export-base firms, such as business tax cuts.
By targeting export-base firms, business tax incentives have a job-multiplier effect on other local firms. Average multipliers for manufacturing firms are around 2: for each job induced in a manufacturing firm, one other job is created locally.[22]
This job multiplier of 2 helps explain the lower costs per job-year created of average business tax incentives.[23] If tax incentives are targeted at firms with a multiplier of 4, costs can be further reduced, to $7,100 per job-year.
Customized business services have much lower costs. Customized job training is estimated to have a cost per job-year of $3,000.[24] Manufacturing extension is estimated to have a cost per job-year of $2,700.[25]
These customized business services can have low costs because they overcome "market failures" holding back small and medium-sized businesses. Smaller businesses face financing and information barriers in getting the right job-training assistance and business advice. Assistance at modest costs can have larger effects on a smaller business's competitiveness.
Programs to make land ready for development can also have low costs. Redeveloping a distressed neighborhood with services that address neighborhood problems has estimated costs of $1,300 per job-year.[26] Cleaning up brownfields has estimated costs of $1,000 per job-year.[27] Providing infrastructure in depressed regions can have estimated costs of $800 per job-year.[28]
Land development services can be cost-effective because they provide public goods. Improving the transportation access, environmental safety, and amenities associated with land can improve its development potential. Because such improvements often benefit a large area, the private sector is likely to underinvest in such improvements.
Local Earnings Effects of Skills Development Programs
Local economic development is not just about job growth. A higher number of local jobs has its greatest benefits because it increases residents' earnings per capita. Residents' earnings per capita are also boosted by increasing local wages.
A person's wages can be increased by skills development programs. Skills development programs can intervene at any stage of the person's life cycle, from high-quality child care and preschool to K-12 education to college and job training programs. For example, high-quality child care is a skills development program because it helps a child develop better "soft skills," which in turn leads to acquiring other skills later, culminating in better adult skills. As Nobel Prize-winning economist James Heckman has said, "Skills beget skills."[29]
Does investing in skills development for residents lead to increases in local earnings per capita? Local earnings effects depend on whether higher-skilled residents stay or move away from the area. Americans are less mobile than is sometimes understood: half of all Americans, and 40 percent of college graduates, spend most of their working career in their childhood metropolitan area (Bartik 2009).
Moreover, skills acquisition by some residents benefits other residents. If the skills of some residents increase, these higher skills not only increase their own earnings but also increase earnings of other residents (Moretti 2004). For example, when 1 percent of the area population gets a college degree, this directly increases average area earnings by 1.4 percent, since a college degree increases the average earnings of each person in this 1 percent by 140 percent. But beyond that, studies suggest that because of this higher percentage of college-educated workers in the local community, the other 99 percent of the population will get earnings increases of 1.2 percent. Thus, overall area earnings will go up by 2.6 percent, almost twice the direct effect on the individuals getting college degrees.
Why do skills have these local "spillover" benefits? One theory is that business productivity depends upon teamwork, coordination, and idea sharing among many workers, both within and across firms. Even if an individual worker is skilled, a firm may not invest in new technologies unless most of the firm's workers are skilled. A firm may benefit from hiring workers from other firms. In addition, a firm's competitiveness may depend in part upon whether its local suppliers are able to provide it with a quality product at a low price, which will indirectly depend on the skills of these local suppliers' workers.
Figure 5 presents ratios of the present value of the local earnings increase, per dollar of program costs, for skills development programs. These ratios are based on estimates of the direct earnings effects, the proportion of workers staying in the area, and local spillovers. The figure also shows the ratio of earnings increases to program costs for an "average" business tax incentive. For incentives, the earnings increases are based on how job creation affects earnings per capita due to increasing local employment-to-population ratios.[30]
All these skills development programs have local benefits, in higher earnings per capita, that far exceed program costs.[31] Benefit-cost ratios range from just over 2-to-1 to over 8-to-1.[32]
Skills programs have higher benefit-cost ratios than typical business tax incentives. Skills programs increase earnings per capita directly, whereas job creation programs only do so indirectly. As discussed above, only 15 percent of new jobs end up boosting residents' job prospects. Job creation programs don't have high benefit-cost ratios unless costs per job are low, which they aren't for typical incentives.
Both early and late skills development can pay off. Preschool has a benefit-cost ratio exceeding 5-to-1,[33] but so do later interventions such as K-12[34] and community-college workforce education.[35] Child care has a lower benefit-cost ratio because of its high costs.[36] College scholarship programs have lower earnings benefits relative to scholarship costs because many scholarships go to individuals who would have completed college anyway.[37]
Skills development programs have two drawbacks. First, some benefits are long delayed. Child care has immediate benefits for parental earnings, and job-training programs have good medium-term benefits, but preschool and K-12 and even college scholarship programs do not fully realize their highest earnings benefits until former participants are in their prime earnings years, after age 40.
Second, these programs' ability to boost wages depends on job availability. In places or times of high unemployment, having more job skills is not enough.
Both drawbacks argue for combining skills development with cost-effective job creation. Job creation can offset a job shortage and provide more immediate benefits.
Grand Rapids as a Case Study
Is there evidence from specific communities that such strategies pay off? Yes. Consider Grand Rapids.
As mentioned, Grand Rapids has done relatively well in recent years in overall job creation, and in manufacturing job creation, compared to other manufacturing-intensive communities, and compared to the United States. What are some strategies accompanying that success?[38]
- Grand Rapids put significant economic development resources into locating a branch manufacturing extension services office.
- The state of Michigan devotes more resources than the average state to customized job training programs.
- The local economic development organization has invested great effort in developing clusters of related manufacturing industries that can work together to identify common problems (e.g., skill needs) and that seek to overcome those problems.
- The local area has a high-profile initiative, Talent 2025, which is trying to improve the area's skills development from early childhood through adulthood.[39]
- Extensive infrastructure investments have been made in downtown Grand Rapids.
- Local business interests put up funds for extensive subsidies that helped attract the medical school of Michigan State University to locate in Grand Rapids.
A specific example of an economic development effort in Grand Rapids was the creation of the West Michigan Medical Device Consortium. According to Atkins et al. (2011, p. 17),
[this] Consortium was formed to give medical device companies throughout the region the opportunity to collaborate, and to promote their specialized expertise in the medical device industry. An automotive parts firm . . . moved into the medical devices market, making [orthopedic] parts. A bakery and wrappings supplier established a medical packaging subsidiary, manufacturing packaging for medical test kits.
These Grand Rapids anecdotes are consistent with overall research on what spurs success in manufacturing-intensive communities.
Conclusion
What policies can help manufacturing-intensive communities? If aggregate U.S. manufacturing job decline is as bad as it was from 2000 to 2009, the answer is "nothing."
Therefore, to help manufacturing-intensive communities, federal policy should be supportive by stabilizing long-run U.S. manufacturing employment. This is possible. Because of global trends, such as increased customization of products, and rising costs in other countries, some manufacturing may move closer to its U.S. markets (Livesey 2017). Better U.S. macroeconomic policies may be able to make exchange rates more favorable to manufacturing.
If overall U.S. manufacturing job numbers stay at about the same level in the long run, then manufacturing-intensive communities have good policy options. Community success can be achieved by making the local economy more productive. Local policies can do the following:
- Help the competitiveness of small and medium-sized manufacturers.
- Make land more developable through better amenities, infrastructure, and environmental cleanup.
- Enhance the skills of the workforce.
Such local policies are best administered, customized, and delivered by local entities. Distressed communities will need financial help from the state and federal government.
The federal government can also help by paying for policy evaluations. Local communities are laboratories of democracy. However, we don't learn much from labs if no one pulls together the results.
What is needed to help manufacturing-intensive communities? Two things: 1) federal policy to make success possible, and 2) local policies that invest in the factors that drive business productivity.
For additional details and analyses, see the longer report: Timothy J. Bartik (2018b),What Works to Help Manufacturing-Intensive Local Economies? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
References
Atkins, Patricia, Pamela Blumenthal, Leah Curran, Adrienne Edisis, Alec Friedhoff, Lisa Lowry, Travis St. Clair, Howard Wial, and Harold Wolman. 2011. Responding to Manufacturing Job Loss: What Can Economic Development Policy Do? Metro Economy Series for the Metropolitan Policy Program at the Brookings Institution. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Bartik, Timothy J. 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
———. 2009. "What Proportion of Children Stay in the Same Location as Adults, and How Does This Vary across Location and Groups?" Upjohn Institute Working Paper No. 09-145. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. http://research.upjohn.org/up_workingpapers/145/(accessed March 26, 2018).
———. 2011. Investing in Kids: Early Childhood Programs and Local Economic Development. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. http://doi.org/10.17848/9780880994002 (accessed March 13, 2018).
———. 2014. From Preschool to Prosperity: The Economic Payoff to Early Childhood Education. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
———. 2015. "How Effects of Local Labor Demand Shocks Vary with the Initial Local Unemployment Rate." Growth and Change 46(4): 529-557.
———. 2018a. Who Benefits from Economic Development Incentives? How Incentive Effects on Local Incomes and the Income Distribution Vary with Different Assumptions about Incentive Policy and the Local Economy. Report. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
———.2018b. What Works to Help Manufacturing-Intensive Local Economies?Technical Report. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
Bartik, Timothy J., Brad Hershbein, and Marta Lachowska. 2016. "The Merits of Universal Scholarships: Benefit-Cost Evidence from the Kalamazoo Promise." Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis 7(3): 400-433. https://doi.org/10.1017/bca.2016.22 (accessed March 26, 2018).
Busso, Matias, Jesse Gregory, and Patrick Kline. 2013. "Assessing the Incidence and Efficiency of a Prominent Place Based Policy." American Economic Review103(2): 897–947. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.2.897 (accessed March 26, 2018).
Ehlen, Mark. 2001. "The Economic Impact of Manufacturing Extension Centers." Economic Development Quarterly 15(1): 36-44.
Hollenbeck, Kevin. 2008. "Is There a Role for Public Support of Incumbent Worker On-the-Job Training?" Upjohn Institute Working Paper No. 08-138. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. http://dx.doi.org/10.17848/wp08-138 (accessed March 26, 2018).
———. 2013. "Public Support of Workforce Training for Incumbent Workers?" Paper. School of Public Policy, University of Maryland.
Hollenbeck, Kevin M., and Wei-Jang Huang. 2014. Net Impact and Benefit-Cost Estimates of the Workforce Development System in Washington State. Upjohn Institute Technical Report No. 13-029. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. https://doi.org/10.17848/tr13-029 (accessed March 26, 2018).
Holzer, Harry J., Richard N. Block, Marcus Cheatham, and Jack H. Knott. 1993. "Are Training Subsidies for Firms Effective? The Michigan Experience." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46(4): 625-636.
Hoyt, William H., Christopher Jepsen, and Kenneth R. Troske. 2008. "Business Incentives and Employment: What Incentives Work and Where?" Working Paper No. 2009-02. Lexington, KY: University of Kentucky, Institute for Federalism and Intergovernmental Relations.
Jackson, C. Kirabo, Rucker C. Johnson, and Claudia Persico. 2016. "The Effects of School Spending on Educational and Economic Outcomes: Evidence from School Finance Reforms." Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(1): 157-218. https://academic.oup.com/qje/article/131/1/157/2461148 (accessed March 24, 2018).
Jarmin, Ronald S. 1998. "Manufacturing Extension and Productivity Dynamics." Discussion Paper No. 98-8. Washington, DC: U.S. Census Bureau.
———. 1999. "Evaluating the Impact of Manufacturing Extension on Productivity Growth." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 18(1): 99-119.
Jensen, Nate. 2017. "Exit Options in Firm-Government Negotiations: An Evaluation of the Texas Chapter 313 Program." Working Paper No. 2017-10. Washington, DC: Washington Center for Equitable Growth.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. 2014. "Local Economic Development, Agglomeration Economies, and the Big Push: 100 Years of Evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority." Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(1): 275-331.
Livesey, Finbarr. 2017. From Global to Local: The Making of Things and the End of Globalization. New York: Pantheon Books.
Miller-Adams, Michelle, Grace Denny, Teresa Behrens, and Michael Moody. 2017. Understanding the Philanthropic Character of Communities: Insights from Two West Michigan Communities. Report. Grand Rapids, MI: Grand Valley State University, Johnson Center for Philanthropy.
Moretti, Enrico. 2004. "Estimating the Social Return to Higher Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data." Journal of Econometrics 121(2004): https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304407603002653 (accessed March 26, 2018).
———. 2010 "Local Multipliers." American Economic Review 100(2): 373-377. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aer.100.2.373 (accessed March 26, 2018).
Paull, Evans. 2008. The Environmental and Economic Impacts of Brownfields Redevelopment. Report. Washington, DC: Northeast-Midwest Institute.
Phillips, Joseph M., and Ernest P. Goss. 1995. "The Effect of State and Local Taxes on Economic Development: A Meta-Analysis." Southern Economic Journal62(2): 320-333.
Suárez Serrato, Juan Carlos, and Owen Zidar. 2016. "Who Benefits from State Corporate Tax Cuts? A Local Labor Market Approach with Heterogeneous Firms." American Economic Review 106(9): 2582-2624.
Van Dijk, Jasper Jacob. 2018. "Robustness of Econometrically Estimated Multipliers across Different Methods and Data." Journal of Regional Science58(2): 281-294.
Wasylenko, Michael J. 1997. "Taxation and Economic Development: The State of the Economic Literature." New England Economic Review 1997(March/April): 37-52.
Zidar, Owen. 2017. "Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth and Employment." Working paper. Chicago: University of Chicago, Booth School of Business; and Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
End Notes
-- via my feedly newsfeed