Sunday, January 21, 2018

Urban Institute: Shocking drop in life expectancy shows the US is still in bad health [feedly]

Shocking drop in life expectancy shows the US is still in bad health
https://www.urban.org/urban-wire/shocking-drop-life-expectancy-shows-us-still-bad-health

This post was originally published by New Scientist.

Five years ago, a groundbreaking report showed people in the US in worse health and dying younger than people in other rich nations. And recently, despite the alarm the report generated, we learned that US life expectancy declined for a second year in a row—astonishing by any standard.

The original report, released by the US National Research Council and Institute of Medicine and subtitled "Shorter Lives, Poorer Health," documented a large and growing US "health disadvantage." As my New Scientist commentary at the time explained, widespread evidence showed that compared with people in other wealthy democracies, people in the US under age 75—men and women, rich and poor, of all races and ethnicities—die younger and experience more injuries and illnesses.

Even a cursory look at developments over the past five years reveals why the country is still so unwell. Public policies and poor living conditions all play a part.

The US is also in the midst of one of the worst drug epidemics in the nation's history. It is a public health crisis that has been unfolding over two decades but only recently garnered urgent national attention. Drug overdoses, often from opioid use, now surpass road accidents as the leading cause of death from injury (as opposed to disease), for people in the US ages 25 to 64. More than 175 people die every day as a result of overdoses, the equivalent of two full 747 jumbo jets crashing every week somewhere in the country.

Along with deaths attributable to alcohol and suicide, the overdoses have been branded "deaths of despair." Compared with other rich nations, the US also continues to experience higher rates of infant mortality and gun deaths.

Taken together, such trends have led to a US life expectancy that stagnated after 2012, dropped for the first time in two decades in 2015, and dropped again in 2016. All this is taking place against a backdrop of growing inequality in income, wealth, and health.

Despite these dismal health outcomes, the US outspends other countries on health care. In 2016, it spent $9,364 per person compared with $4,094 in the UK. US spending on social welfare programs is comparable with that of other rich nations. What distinguishes the US from other countries is how that money is spent: it is less redistributive, with less going to children, families, and people with low incomes.

As the "Shorter Lives" study argues, a key barrier to improvements in health is "limited political support among both the public and policymakers to enact the policies and commit the necessary resources." On this front, too, the US is slipping. Despite its imperfections and needed reforms, the Affordable Care Act (ACA) was a landmark piece of legislation that by 2016 was providing millions of uninsured people access to health insurance for the first time.

Under the Trump administration, Congress has repeatedly tried to repeal the ACA and is poised to weaken it through its recently passed tax bill. It has even allowed the less controversial Children's Health Insurance Program, which provides low-cost health insurance to 9 million children across the country, to go unfunded.

As Americans continue to debate policies in an increasingly divided and polarized country, a health disadvantage decades in the making continues to grow. Until the country bridges some of these divides and acts on the evidence, its people will continue to pay a steep price: shorter lives and poorer health.



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

DeLong: Should-Read : Why hasn't globalization reduced inequality in emerging markets over the past generation? Jeffrey Frankel... [feedly]

Should-Read : Why hasn't globalization reduced inequality in emerging markets over the past generation? Jeffrey Frankel...
http://www.bradford-delong.com/2018/01/should-read-jeffrey-frankel-does-trade-fuel-inequalityhttpswwwproject-syndicateorgcommentaryglobalizatio.html

Should-Read: Why hasn't globalization reduced inequality in emerging markets over the past generation? Jeffrey Frankel wants to say that it is because the HO-SS theory is misleading and unhelpful for inequality issues. I think that is not right. HO-SS says economic integration will reduce inequality if it raises the relative demand for factors of production controlled by the poor. But the most important shift in relative factor abundance has been the ability to plug yourself into the world economy: that is controlled by the rich in emerging markets, and that has become much much scarcer relative to demand: Jeffrey Frankel: Does Trade Fuel Inequality?: "Trade has been among the most powerful drivers of... the convergence between the developed and developing worlds...

...The HO-SS theory, which dominated international economic thinking from the 1950s through 1970s, predicted that international trade would benefit the abundant factor of production (in rich countries, the owners of capital) and hurt the scarce factor of production (in rich countries, unskilled labor).... Then... Paul Krugman and Elhanan Helpman introduced... imperfect competition and increasing returns... Marc Melitz... shift[ing] resources from low-productivity to high-productivity firms.... Not all of the HO-SS theory's predictions have come true.... Pinelopi Goldberg and Nina Pavcnik.... "There is overwhelming evidence," they write, "that less-skilled workers in developing countries "are generally not better off, at least not relative to workers with higher skill or education levels."... Ten years later, inequality continues to worsen within developing countries, including the so-called BRICS.... This does not mean that the forces described by the HO-SS theory are irrelevant. But there is clearly more to current inequality trends than trade.... Inequality is clearly a serious problem that merits political attention. But focusing on trade is not the way to resolve it...

VISIT WEBSITE

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Dani Rodrik: More on distinguishing ideas and interests -- an exchange with Peter Hall [feedly]

More on distinguishing ideas and interests -- an exchange with Peter Hall
http://rodrik.typepad.com/dani_rodriks_weblog/2018/01/more-on-distinguishing-ideas-and-interests-an-exchange-with-peter-hall.html

My recent post on ideas versus interests elicited some comments from Peter Hall, my Harvard colleague who has done probably more thinking on this issue than any other scholar I know. With his permission, I am attaching these comments below, along with the brief subsequent exchange we have had.

________________________________

Dani,

A few quick thoughts inspired by your recent blog post on ideas and interests.  As you know, this is a topic that has long interested me.  These are rather cryptic thoughts (ars longa, vitae brevis) but I pass them along in case they are stimulating.

You are, of course, right to observe that interests are always interpreted (by ideas), i.e. they do not arise unambiguously from the material world.  And I think you are on the right track when you contrast the 'ex ante' account from interests with an ideas account of outcomes. 

But one might put even more emphasis (than I gather you do?) on the implication, which is that people always act based on both their ideas and their interests.  That is to say it is impossible to have perceptions of interest without ideas (and it is those perceptions of interest rather than the interests in themselves that motivate actors). 

Thus, claims that people are acting on their 'interest' are, in effect, claims that they are acting in line with some conventional set of ideas about what those interests are.  The classic example would be analyses that attribute to actors a set of interests that a conventional understanding of neoclassical economics would ascribe to anyone in their socioeconomic position.  The implicit claim of such analyses must be that those actors understand their position in that way, i.e. in line with these conventional ideas.

On my reading, this is what you mean when you associate interest-based arguments with a 'parsimonious' account of the attributes of the actors.  I do wonder whether parsimonious is the correct characteristic to highlight here (ie thinness vs thickness) since the ideas that underpin such action can be rather 'thick' (in the sense of depending on a relatively elaborate worldview).  The more important point, I think, is that these actors operate out of a worldview that can readily be seen as 'conventional' (in the sense of that term that it is widely-accepted as orthodox).

Now, there may be small sets of actors who in certain circumstances act against their 'interests' in the sense that they realize, by virtue of the ideas they hold, that they will lose something they value (material goods, power, etc.) by so acting.  And those actors might do that as a result of holding (other) sets of ideas, eg. of the sort associated with some sort of 'altruism'.  Soldiers who sacrifice themselves in battle might fall into that category.  However, I suspect that this is a very small category of people and, in many instances, as your argument intuits, such people could be said to have an unconventional view of their interest which dictates their action.

To continue then with the main account, if my view is correct, it becomes interesting to inquire about the role of ideas when there is (some kind of) contestation about precisely what is in the interest of the actors.  In your terms, these are cases in which ideas become salient to action And it turns out that is a relatively-common occurrence.  Thus, ideas often have influence over action, and the key problem is to explain (make claims about) why some ideas become influential in specific contexts while others do not.

With regard to that problem, it must surely be the case that a specific set of ideas (relative to other ideas) are more likely to become influential when they bear directly on the interests of the actors (understood as gains/losses of power or goods that the actor values).  Actors usually gravitate toward ideas that seem to them to serve their interests, understood in this stripped-down fashion. This is why interests and ideas typically bear together on action. 

What sorts of implications follow from this?

  • The Germans are probably not acting out of 'interest' independently of ideas. They are influenced by (Hayekian) ideas that tell them that their current posture is in the national interest as they construe it.  And, if we want to think of the latter as some sort of stripped-down 'material' interest, we have to bear in mind, first, that this conception of material interest is itself underpinned by an explicit set of ideas and, second, that there are other ways to interpret national interest and even material national interest.  For instance, policies that provoke a second Euro crisis might not ultimately be in that interest.  In other words, your initial point that all 'interests' must be interpreted by 'ideas' means that we cannot claim that interests trump ideas in instances such as this.
  • Although ideas are, on this view, important in all cases, we can detect, as you argue, instances that are distinctive by virtue of something about the prominence of the role that ideas play in them, such as the case of the Reagan tax cut. The issue is: what is distinctive about such instances?  I would argue it is not that ideas are somehow more important than interests in such instances.  After all, making the tax cuts was very much in the political interest of the Reagan administration.  What is distinctive is that there was contestation, with significant numbers of partisans on each side, about how to interpret (in this case) the economic interests of the populace.  It is the presence of contestation, rather than the importance of ideas, that distinguishes this case.
  • My bottom line is that the analytical way forward is not to ask: 'can we distinguish cases in which ideas were more important or influential from cases in which they were not?' but rather to ask: 'how might we best distinguish between situations in which ideas play a somewhat different role in the interaction between interests and ideas that underpins all action?'.

Don't hold me to this.  These are difficult issues and I find my views on them changing over time.  But I hope this is stimulating.

Peter

____________________________

Dear Peter

Thank you very much for this. It is incredibly helpful, and I agree with much of it.

I am all for pursuing the agenda you set out at the very end – tracing out the different ways in which ideas affect interests and their interaction with prevailing ideational environment. But I would like to resist the formulation where interests are always subservient to ideas, which this approach presumes. There is a sense in which this is true, and you put it very well yourself in your note. A statement of the form, "the industry pursued its interest" must have some meaning, even though at the end of the day what we really mean to say is "the industry pursued its interest, as it perceived its interest to be."

We are often concerned with explaining changes. Why did an actor change its behavior? There is substantive difference, it seems to me, between two sort of explanations:

  • an explanation that relies on behavior in the context of an unchanged understanding of what the actor's interests are. The actor's utility function and its understanding of how the world works stay the same, but there are changes in the world it confronts. For example, the constraints it faces are altered.
  • An explanation that relies on a change in the actor's understanding of what its interests are. The actor's utility function changes or its understanding of how the world works is altered.

The distinction I would like to make is that case (a) is what many realists have in mind in IR or rational choice political economists tend to focus on. And I think it is OK to call these cases interest-driven cases.

Case (b) would fall in my ideational category.

Just like you, I am not sure about any of this. But we should try to figure out a way of thinking these issues more.

Best

Dani

______________________________

Dani,

What you say makes excellent sense.  Focusing on cases of change is very promising.  And the distinction you draw between (a) and (b) a compelling one.  I agree that ideas do not trump interests.  The latter are just as important to be sure.

Of course, some of the most interesting cases are ones with features of both (a) and (b), i.e. constraints/opportunities in the world change and (partly by virtue of that) there is consideration, albeit not always adoption, of new ideas.  But the distinction strikes me as an excellent starting point.

Peter



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Links, and some warm music for these chilly times [feedly]

Links, and some warm music for these chilly times
http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/links-and-some-warm-music-for-these-chilly-times/

Links, and some warm music for these chilly times

NOTES

Add note

–Ask not for whom the shutdown tolls. It tolls for thee. IE, it does if you're someone who recognizes the need for functional gov't. Over at WaPo.

To be clear, this is not a critique of the D senators that are blocking the deal. As a friend puts it, "They are forcing governance in the face of total bad faith and incompetence from the other side, and shouldn't be shy in saying that."

Or doing it. Trump and much of the R caucus have put every partisan priority before DACA and CHIP, programs that have bipartisan support (despite McConnell's nonsense  claim that DACA is preference of the D's "far-left base." As the minority, they're using the tools at their disposal to fight for permanent solutions to problems that both sides claim to want to address.

Still, here's my bottom line:

But abstracting from this latest episode, the broader dysfunction is strategic. It is not politically neutral. "A pox on both their houses" doesn't capture its essence. It is driven by too many policymakers who, in so many words, argue that Washington is broken, and they will make sure it stays that way.

While political pundits are actively debating which party will get blamed for the current mess, at the end of the day, the real losers are those of us who firmly believe that a functioning, representative, amply funded public sector is essential to the well-being of the people, especially the majority without the resources to offset market failures with their wealth holdings.

Instead, the majority party under a completely feckless leader is busy transferring the nation's wealth from the Treasury to the top few percent, adding to the debt while arguing that this higher debt requires cuts in spending on behalf of moderate and low-income households. At the same time, by refusing to compromise with those whose votes they need to keep the government open, they're turning up the dysfunction dial to further undermine the notion that the government can help meet the challenges we face, those that the private sector will not meet, including rising inequality, climate change, health and retirement insecurity, deteriorating public infrastructure and more.

Again, this hurts all of us who don't have the wealth to insulate ourselves from the hurt, and when it comes to climate change, even your massive wealth portfolio won't protect you.

–Vox has a piece challenging any Trumpian credit for the historically low black unemployment rate. Obviously. I made this figure to underscore the point that Trump's riding a trend he inherited.

Source: BLS, HP Trend

–Finally, I see that where Steve 'Grizzly' Nisbett, the drummer of the great reggae band Steel Pulse, who's music I've featured here before. His beautiful spirit, along with his smooth riddim's–here's a great example–will be sorely missed.

Speaking of Jah's soundtrack, I can't stop listening to the great, young artist Chronixx. Here are a couple of crucial eg's.

"I'm pleased
To be chillin' in the West Indies
Jah provides all my wants and needs
I got the sunshine and rivers and trees."



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Slowly but Surely, a Farewell to Fossil Fuels [feedly]

Slowly but Surely, a Farewell to Fossil Fuels
https://blogs.imf.org/2018/01/18/slowly-but-surely-a-farewell-to-fossil-fuels/

Repairs to an oil rig in North Dakota, United States: Eighty percent of the world's energy consumption is based on fossil fuels (photo: North Dakota/Jim Gehrz/MCT/Newscom).

This has never happened before. Never. Three years of stagnating carbon dioxide emissions coupled with relatively healthy global economic growth. In this podcast , International Energy Agency Chief Economist Laszlo Varro talks about leaving fossil fuels in the past.

Eighty percent of the world's energy consumption is based on fossil fuels, which account for most of the greenhouse gases that are warming the planet . Varro was recently invited to speak to IMF economists about the impact of climate change on energy policy.  He says that achieving broad-based GDP growth in all the major regions of the global economy, while also decreasing emissions, was possible due to the declining energy intensity of the Chinese economy, rapid, large-scale investments in renewable energy—especially in solar power—and a large-scale shift from use of coal to natural gas.

"When economies shift from using coal to using gas, which is a very powerful structural shift that is ongoing in the United States, and to a lesser degree also in China, and it has an impact on reducing carbon emissions," Varro says.

To successfully further decrease reliance on fossil fuels, Varro says there must be a persistent push on renewable and low-carbon energy sources into electricity, because the overwhelming majority of clean energy investment is in the electricity sector.

"There are technological solutions, but countries have to rethink their electricity regulations in a quite comprehensive fashion," he says.

Varro concedes that electricity has its limits with the current state of technology. For example, do not expect to see an electric aircraft anytime soon. So, countries need to continue to innovate to develop other technological solutions that will replace fossil fuels, he says.

Large-scale shifts in economies rarely comes without some political challenges, and job losses are usually at the forefront. Varro says how technology affects employment is absolutely a concern, but he does not think that shifts in energy sources is the largest part of this.

"In the past 12 months in the U.S., the retail industry lost more jobs because of Amazon than the coal industry's job losses in the last five years combined," he says.

Listen to the podcast:

Other readables:

End of the Oil Age: Not Whether But When

Chart of the Week: Electric Takeover in Transportation  

Countries Are Signing Up for Sizeable Carbon Prices



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Friday, January 19, 2018

James Galbraith: What Trump’s Tax Cut Really Means for the US Economy [feedly]

What Trump's Tax Cut Really Means for the US Economy

James Galbraith

Republicans and the Trump administration have promised that the tax legislation enacted in December will boost investment and the rate of GDP growth over the long term. But the new law is likely to do neither, because it is based on flawed assumptions and contains a raft of self-defeating provisions.

AUSTIN – The Trump administration's stated economic-policy objective is to increase growth in the United States from the post-financial-crisis rate of around 2% to at least 3%. In historical terms, achieving such growth is not out of the question. Real (inflation-adjusted) GDP growth exceeded 3% in 2005-2006 and 4% in the period from 1997 to 2000; and in each of the past two quarters, the economy has grown at an annualized rate above 3%. The question is whether that pace can be sustained.

Despite low headline unemployment – 4.1% as of December – the US economy is neither at full employment nor constrained by labor supply, as some have argued. The employment-to-population ratio has risen from its post-crisis low of around 58% to just over 60%, but it is still three percentage points below the 2007 level, and five points below its peak in 2000. While many workers retired during and after the post-crisis recession, some could be lured back to work for pay. And while net immigration has slowed, it would pick up, if more workers were needed.

Because infrastructure investment and serious trade protection have (apparently) been removed from the agenda, the growth strategy advocated by Trump and congressional Republicans now boils down to the tax law that they rushed to enact in December. Featuring a major cut in the corporate-tax rate and accelerated expensing for capital investments, the law could have two distinct effects: a fiscal-policy effect on aggregate demand and a "supply-side" effect on the economy's productive capacity.

In the first four years, when the law's net tax cuts will be equal to around 0.9% of GDP per year, the stimulative effect will depend on how much of the additional private income is spent in a given year, and on the fiscal multiplier applied to that spending. Assuming, generously, that 60% of the additional private income is spent each year, and that the fiscal multiplier is 1.5, the tax cut would initially add almost one percentage point to the rate of GDP growth. But that would be a one-time effect. Annual GDP would climb higher once, but the long-run growth rate would not be affected.

Moreover, if the lost revenue is offset by automatic cuts to Medicare or Social Security benefits, or by reductions in spending by state and local governments, the tax package will have even less of a net fiscal effect, because it will drive down public and private purchases of goods and services. Still, on the further generous (and problematic) assumption that the US Federal Reserve does not respond, the tax cut could keep the real growth rate above 3% through 2018, and perhaps also through 2019.

THE QUESTION OF GROWTH

To determine if the tax legislation will have any cumulative effect on the long-run growth rate, we should turn to a debate, published by Project Syndicate in December, between Robert J. Barro and his Harvard colleagues Jason Furman and Lawrence H. Summers. In the debate's first installment, Barro used a neoclassical growth model to calculate that the tax law will boost the growth rate by about 0.3% per year, implying a gain of 2.8% in per capita GDP over the next ten years.

In their response, Furman and Summers accepted Barro's growth model, but criticized his application of it. Their strategy was brilliant, insofar as it narrowed the killing ground. After making various corrections to Barro's underlying assumptions about the tax plan, they used his own model to show that his calculation is off by "an order of magnitude." A modest effect was thus rendered essentially negligible.

To understand why, we should first consider Barro's model, which he insists is in keeping with common practices in the economics profession. Accordingly, he equates the tax law's effect on the "user costs that businesses attach to investment" with the "marginal product of capital" in "economists' most popular model of economic growth." He then estimates an elasticity of 1.25 for the "capital/labor ratio to user cost,", in a "Cobb-Douglas production function (commonly used by economists)." Through it all, what he really seems to be saying is: Don't bother me with quibbles over theory.But Furman and Summers left Barro's core theoretical assumptions unchallenged. So, while they demolished his claim that the tax law will have a significant effect on long-term growth, they seemed to concede that a plan with even greater benefits for corporate profits and even more generous expensing provisions would have done more. To my mind, this inference is false, and could dangerously mislead policymakers in future debates over tax legislation.

Next come the numbers. Based on his assumptions about elasticity and other factors, Barro calculates a 25% increase in the long-term capital-labor ratio for non-residential corporate structures – bank buildings, shopping malls, and so forth – and a 17% increase for corporate equipment. Let's say the overall increase would be somewhere in the middle, around 20%. That means Barro expects the tax package to add another $10 trillion to the US capital stock, which is worth roughly $50 trillion today.

After making a modest downward adjustment, Barro concludes that this added capital stock would boost long-run GDP by 7%, or by about $1.2 trillion in 2009 dollars. That means he expects a net tax cut of $1.5 trillion over ten years – with just $644 billion of it going to businesses – eventually to generate a six-fold gain in capital stock, and 80 cents on the dollar in real annual output after about 14 years.

This would truly be a miracle of loaves and fishes. Obviously, Barro's numbers are preposterous, and Furman and Summers are right to dispute them. Nonetheless, they still describe Barro's underlying model as "sensible." Perhaps they are adhering to a Cambridge code of politesse that enjoins them from calling things by their right name.

NEOCLASSICAL FALLACIES

Barro's model assumes that corporate-tax cuts, by increasing the after-tax productivity of the capital stock, will induce businesses to create more capital until the marginal product of capital (units of output per unit of input) returns to its long-run equilibrium level, as determined by the discount and depreciation rates. If labor is fully employed, the increases in capital will boost total output. And, in the meantime, capital's share in total output will grow as the wage share declines, because the initial capital investment has to be paid for with wage cuts, higher taxes on labor, spending cuts to social programs, or by borrowing and incurring the costs of future interest and principal repayments. After all, in neoclassical economics, nothing comes from nothing.

The first problem with this model is that there is no good reason to assume that higher after-tax profits will generate investments in more capital-intensive modes of production. Barro is confusing the after-tax profitability of existing activity with the prospective profitability of new investment. Furman and Summers understand this, which is why they favor more expensing for new capital investment and a smaller reduction in the corporate-tax rate.


But Barro adds further confusion with his treatment of the expected profitability of new investment and the resulting capital-labor ratio. His model regards capital as homogeneous, and makes a distinction only between structures and equipment. But the fact is that firms base investment decisions not just on their view of future profits, but on the state of technology at the time.

Normally, new technologies determine the right mix of structures, equipment, and labor. And because digital technologies tend to save both capital and labor, a lower relative price for capital equipment does not necessarily lead to higher relative use of "capital." If the price of construction or equipment such as computers or touch screens falls while wages do not, the resulting business operation would actually appear to be more labor-intensive than it was before. In fact, this seems to describe many business situations today. The low share of investment in GDP in recent years reflects the relatively low cost of new electronic machinery, which has shifted more of the burden of sustaining growth onto consumption.

It is a neoclassical fallacy to think that businesses can simply swap in structures for labor as a way to boost the capital-labor ratio and achieve their output goal at the desired cost. The entire point of building a nonresidential structure – be it a hospital, a factory, or a big-box store – is to fill it with workers and machines. If businesses take advantage of more generous expensing provisions to build or acquire additional structures without the machines or workers, they won't be increasing their output or productivity; they'll just be taking up space.

Moreover, because new electronic machinery is physically compact and tends to displace office and administrative labor, business structures are less necessary today than during the golden ages of automotive manufacturing, insurance, or banking. And because so much new equipment is now imported, the multiplier on many investments will not be felt in the US, but rather in the countries producing the capital goods. No tax law will change these facts.

So, even when future investments do occur, they aren't likely to raise the capital-labor ratio or the real rate of growth. And even if Barro, Furman, and Summers were to argue that new capital equipment is "better" and thus amounts to "more," that doesn't change the fact that the actual cost of equipment and the share of investment in output (in dollar terms) may both be falling.

BACK TO REALITY

Clearly, Barro's model – and not just his particular use of it – is absurd. A better alternative would focus on the political economy and business behavior. Such an analysis yields claims that are less absolute in their certainty; and that is a good thing.

In the real world, businesses invest for two reasons: to expand production and to reduce costs. The first reason requires confidence in future sales growth. The new tax law could be expected to boost sales in the near term, owing to its one-time fiscal effect. And yet it seems to take direct aim at middle-class purchasing power, by capping deductions for mortgage-interest payments and state and local taxes (SALT). That, in turn, will result in less consumer demand and lower spending on public services. Rather than creating a climate favorable to private consumption and investment, the law's vast upward redistribution of income and wealth is bound to depress spending, regardless of whether businesses are allowed to retain a larger share of their cash flows.

Complicating matters further, the Fed's response to the tax law, and what effect monetary-policy adjustments will have on the economy, remains to be seen. Historically, there have been occasions when an interest-rate hike set the stage for a long-term business boom, such as in February 1994, when Fed policy prompted banks to move out of safe instruments and back into commercial and industrial loans. But at that time, the technology revolution was still looming, and banks needed a push to decrease their reliance on a steep yield curve. The same pattern is not likely to repeat itself today.

Today, if the Fed decides to increase interest rates more quickly, the value of the dollar will rise, and imported capital goods will become even more attractive relative to those produced domestically, thus hurting growth. Moreover, some analysts worry about an impending funding crisis in the rest of the world, which would trigger a flight toward safer assets such as Treasuries, further intensifying dollar appreciation. If that led to another financial crisis, the weak position of some of the world's largest banks would be exposed, and the period of growth would end. Barro's model has no place for financial risk. But the firms being encouraged to make new investments certainly do.

One area where the tax law could actually generate a boost is in commercial construction, if incumbent firms collectively decide to expand to protect their market share, an anticompetitive process the economist Joseph Schumpeter called "co-respective behavior." Likewise, the favorable tax treatment on structures might enable dominant firms to muscle in on the remaining market share of small retailers, restaurants, and other service providers. If so, we can expect to see a bubble, followed by a bust, in commercial structures.

The chances of this happening are not negligible. As the architects of the new tax package surely know, the last two economic expansions, in the late 1990s and in the mid-2000s, were the result of asset bubbles generated by co-respective behavior, first on the part of technology investors, and then on the part of speculators in corrupt mortgages. To be sure, a new bubble would generate some applause and political benefits in the short term. But the aftermath would not be pretty.

OLIGARCHS, REST ASSURED

Barring a construction bubble, there are two other possibilities for the months and years ahead. First, the law might produce a surge in after-tax corporate cash flows, which will be diverted ("stolen" may be too strong a word, though only barely) toward executive compensation, stock buy-backs, and real-estate holdings, especially if homes, having lost their privileged tax status, are sold off and converted into rental properties. In this scenario, America's oligarchy may become somewhat larger and more diverse, and its spending could even provide a modest short-term boost to real GDP growth; but a bust would inevitably follow.

The other possibility is that corporations, having secured more favorable tax treatment, will actually curtail their investments. Corporate executives will not be blind to the prospect of a general slowdown in consumption following the law's initial fiscal effect, especially as state and local governments are forced to retrench under pressure from middle-class constituents who can no longer deduct SALT expenses at the federal level.

In this second scenario, the Polish economist MichaƂ Kalecki's adage that "capitalists get what they spend" will apply. After-tax profits might not rise by much, and America's oligarchs will remain fat and happy, while doing even less. The cost will be borne by middle-class Americans with mortgages and homes that they might now want to sell; and, as always, by the poor, who will suffer from higher sales taxes, social-spending cuts, and unemployment.

And why should anyone expect a different outcome? After all, this isn't just Trump's tax plan. It is what the Republican donor class has always wanted.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed