Friday, December 8, 2017

Paul Krugman: Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits [feedly]

Paul Krugman: Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits
http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2017/12/paul-krugman-republicans-are-coming-for-your-benefits.html

offsetting those deficits will require going after the true big-ticket programs, namely Medicare and Social Security":

Republicans Are Coming for Your Benefits, by Paul Krugman, NY Times: ...During the Senate debate over the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, Senator Orrin Hatch was challenged over support for the Children's Health Insurance Program, which covers nine million U.S. children — but whose funding lapsed two months ago... Hatch ... insisted that "the reason CHIP's having trouble is because we don't have money anymore" — just before voting for a trillion-and-a-half-dollar tax cut that will deliver the bulk of its benefits to the richest few percent....
He then went on to say, "I have a rough time wanting to spend billions and billions and trillions of dollars to help people who won't help themselves, won't lift a finger and expect the federal government to do everything."
So who, exactly, was he talking about...?
Was he talking about food stamps, most of whose beneficiaries are children, elderly or disabled? ... Was he talking about the earned-income tax credit, which rewards only those who work? Was he talking about Medicaid, which again mainly benefits children, the elderly and the disabled, plus people who work hard but whose jobs don't provide health benefits?
We can go on down the list. The simple fact is that big spending on people who "won't lift a finger" doesn't actually happen in America — only in Hatch's meanspirited imagination.
Now, to be fair..., some people ... get lots of money they didn't lift a finger to earn — namely, inheritors of large estates. ...Republican legislation would give these people ... billions and billions of dollars... How can this be justified if it's supposedly hard to find money for children's health care?
Well, Senator Chuck Grassley explained it all last week: "I think not having the estate tax recognizes the people that are investing, as opposed to those that are just spending every darn penny they have, whether it's on booze or women or movies." ...
The important thing to realize, however, is that the hypocrisy and contempt for the public we've seen ... is just the beginning..., budget deficits are going to soar... And offsetting those deficits will require going after the true big-ticket programs, namely Medicare and Social Security.
Oh, they'll find euphemisms to describe what they're doing, talking solemnly about the need for "entitlement reform" as an act of fiscal responsibility — while their huge budget-busting tax cut for the rich gets shoved down the memory hole. But whatever words they use to cloak the reality of the situation, Republicans have given their donors what they wanted — and now they're coming for your benefits.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

The distribution of TCJA cuts, as well as the burden of financing them, by income group and race [feedly]

The distribution of TCJA cuts, as well as the burden of financing them, by income group and race
http://www.epi.org/blog/distribution-tax-cuts-and-jobs-act-by-income-race/

The House and Senate both passed versions of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) in recent weeks. Both versions of the bill, which must now be reconciled and voted on again, are made up mostly of large, hugely regressive tax cuts that give disproportionate benefits to big corporations and the wealthiest Americans. While the regressivity of these bills by income class has been well-documented by now, we've been asked by a number of people about the likely distribution of tax cuts called for by the TCJA across racial groups. A fully fleshed-out and precise estimate of this racial distribution would take lots of time and effort to calculate, but a decent rough estimate can be made pretty quickly if we're willing to use some plausible proxy data.

However, it is also crucially important to note that congressional Republicans have not just passed versions of the TCJA in recent weeks, they have also passed a budget resolution calling for steep cuts to key programs, in large part because they want this money to finance their tax cuts. Assessing the impact of tax cuts while ignoring likely spending cuts would lead to a radical underestimate of the effect of coming fiscal policy changes on typical Americans' livelihoods. Given this, we also examine the likely distribution of the burden of financing the TCJA with spending cuts by income class and race.

The Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center (TPC) has provided estimates of what share of the tax cuts would go to different income groups. The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) provides data on the share of households in each of various income groupings that are headed by white, African American, or Hispanic householders. The SCF is uniquely useful here because it has clear income percentile rankings all the way up to the top 1 percent. Merging the TPC and SCF data in this way is not a pure apples-to-apples comparison. The TPC data is arranged by "tax units" while the SCF data is arranged by households (while the SCF calls their unit of analysis "families", it is much closer to the "household" definition used by surveys like the Census). A tax unit can contain more than one household. But, all this said, there still should be substantial overlap between the two data measures, and the TPC data on tax units should provide a useful overview of the distribution of tax cuts across households.

The first row of Table 1 below shows the current distribution of income by income percentile class. The next four rows show the share of each income percentile class that is white, African American, Hispanic and "other" (in the coding of the SCF). Unsurprisingly, white families constitute the majority of every income percentile group. But it is striking (if not surprising) that their share is lowest in the bottom two-fifths of the income distribution and highest in the top 1 percent. Both African American and Hispanic shares are highest in the bottom two fifths and fall monotonically as one moves higher in income percentile rankings. The upshot of this for the distribution of policy changes is crystal-clear: regressive policy changes are likely to inflict the most damage (or provide the least benefit) to non-white families.

Table 1

The sixth and seventh rows of Table 1 shows the distribution of the TCJA tax cuts by income percentile class, for both the House and Senate versions of the bill. As has been pointed out before, the benefits of both versions of this tax cut are astoundingly regressive, with the overall top 1 percent claiming 47.6 and 62.6 percent of total benefits in the House and Senate versions respectively, while the bottom 40 percent of tax units claim less than 2 percent of the total benefits of the House bill and actually see tax increases from the Senate bill.

But as many analysts have noted, examining only the direct effect of tax cuts without accounting for how these cuts will be financed in the long-run is likely to lead to wildly misleading conclusions about their effects. Given this, Table 1 also shows the distributional impact by income percentile class of two illustrative ways that the tax cut could be financed.

The first financing method examined is simply be a lump-sum tax increase on tax units – every tax unit paying an identical dollar sum large enough to neutralize the economy-wide, overall cost of the TCJA (this lump-sum financing was examined by TPC). It could be objected that this is quite unrealistic: lump-sum taxes don't exist in the real world and won't be used to finance the tax cut. This is fair enough – but the entire economic argument that the TCJA will lead to economic growth implicitly presumes that the taxes cut in the framework will be offset by financing that has no behavioral effect at all – which can essentially only occur with lump-sum tax increases. The distribution of the burden of financing the TCJA with a lump-sum increase is predictably regressive. The bottom two-fifths would bear 50.1 percent of the burden while the top 1 percent would face just 0.7 percent.1

Finally, Table shows the distributional impact by income group of financing the TCJA tax cuts with across-the-board cuts in all federal spending except Social Security and defense. This is a rough but fair characterization of the budget resolution passed last month by the Senate and House – very large cuts to all spending except these programs. In fact, the budget resolution, if anything, directed cuts more regressively than an across-the-board cut in non-defense, non-Social Security spending might indicate. For example, cuts to Medicaid fall much more heavily on the bottom of the income distribution than do cuts to Medicare. But Medicare remains a larger overall expenditure, yet the budget resolution directed larger cuts to Medicaid than Medicare.

Yet even with an assumption that actually lightens the likely regressivity of the Congressional budget resolution, this method of financing the TJCA would still result in a steeply regressive burden, with the bottom two-fifths bearing 38.7 percent of the cut (as opposed to their income share of just 13.1 percent) just while the top 1 percent faces just 4.4 percent (relative to their 15.3 percent income share).2

The information in this table allows us to show the total share of income, tax cuts and the burden of financing them that is faced by families by income percentile and race. Table 2shows the share of total income, the share of tax cuts and the share of the burden of financing these tax cuts facing white, African American and Hispanic families in each income percentile class. The first block of rows simply shows the shares of total income accounted for by race and income percentile. So, for example, white families in the bottom fifth of the income distribution account for 2.6 percent of total income, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth account for 1.1 and 0.5 percent of total income, respectively. White families in the top 1 percent account for 14.1 percent of total income, while African American and Hispanic families in the top 1 percent account for 0.2 and 0.3 percent of total income (shares that are low because so few African American and Hispanic families are in the overall top 1 percent).

Table 2

The next two blocks show the shares of the TCJA tax cuts by race and income percentile, for both the House and Senate versions. For the House bill, the first row in this block of columns, for example, shows that 0.2 percent of the benefits of the House TCJA go to white families in the bottom fifth of the income distribution, 0.1 percent of the benefits go to African Americans in the bottom fifth, and less than 0.005 percent goes to Hispanic families in the bottom fifth.

Moving to the top 1 percent row, this shows that 44.1 percent of the benefits of the House TCJA go to white families in the top 1 percent, 0.6 percent go to African American families in the top 1 percent, and 1.0 percent go to Hispanic families in the top 1 percent. The final row sums these to show total benefits of the tax cut by race, but it is important to realize that (for example), while 90.3 percent of the total benefits go to white families, this is driven overwhelmingly by just the top 1 percent.

For the Senate bill, the bottom 40 percent of all races see tax increases from the TCJA. Moving to the top 1 percent row, 58.0 percent of the benefits of the Senate TCJA go to white families in the top 1 percent, 0.8 percent go to African American families in the top 1 percent, and 1.3 percent go to Hispanic families in the top 1 percent. The final row sums these to show total benefits of the tax cut by race, but it is important to realize that (for example), while 90.1 percent of the total benefits go to white families, this is driven overwhelmingly by just the top 1 percent.

The next group of rows shows the distribution of the burden of financing these tax cuts if done with lump-sum taxes, by both income percentile class and race. Again, the first row can be read to show that white families in the bottom fifth would bear 16.5 percent of the total burden of financing tax cuts with lump-sum increases, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth would bear 6.7 and 3.5 percent, respectively. White families in the top 1 percent would bear just 0.6 percent of the total cost of financing tax cuts with lump-sum tax increases, while African American and Hispanic families would bear less than 0.05 percent of the burden. These numbers on lump-sum tax burden do not perfectly reflect population shares because there are more tax units in the lower fifths of the population than in higher fifths. This, combined with higher African American and Hispanic shares in these lower fifths, means that a lump-sum tax levied on tax units will hit them disproportionately.

Finally, the fourth set of bars shows the distribution of the burden of financing these tax cuts if it was done with an across-the-board cutback in government spending, except for defense and Social Security. Again, despite making an assumption that softens how regressive the spending cut in the Congressional budget resolution would be, the burden still falls heavily on non-white families because of the overall regressivity. White families in the bottom fifth would bear 10.3 percent of the burden, while African American and Hispanic families in the bottom fifth would bear 4.2 and 2.2 percent. White families in the top 1 percent would bear just 4 percent of the burden, while African American and Hispanic families in the top 1 percent would both bear 0.1 percent of the burden.

The regressive distribution of both benefits from the TCJA and the burden of financing them is near-entirely a function of income ranking. But we know that the historical legacy of racism and discrimination has led to a non-random distribution of racial groups across the income distribution, with the result that white families overall would see larger benefits from tax cuts and would bear lighter burdens from financing them, while non-white families see smaller gains but larger burdens from the TCJA. To be clear, the benefits even across white families are extraordinarily concentrated at the top – a third of white families will see outright tax increases from the Senate bill, for example. But we shouldn't be blind to disproportionate racial costs and benefits from fiscal policies.

1. Calculating the burden of financing tax cuts with lump-sum tax increases is done by simply taking Tax Policy Center (TPC) estimates of the share of total tax units in each income percentile class. The lower fifths of the income distribution tend to have more tax units (i.e. relatively more single filers), so, a lump-sum tax levied on tax units would fall more heavily on lower-income tax units.

2. Calculating the burden of financing tax cuts with across-the-board cuts in government spending except Social Security and Defense is done by using data from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO). The CBO provides data that allows estimates on the distribution of total transfer payments except for Social Security by income percentile class. CBO also provides guidance on how to distributionally allocate the benefit of federal government consumption and investment spending (or non-transfer spending). The CBO suggest two methods – allocating the benefit of this as a lump-sum across the population, or allocating benefits proportional to income. We allocate non-transfer spending by taking a simple average of these two approaches. We then weight the transfer and non-transfer cuts by current shares of transfers and non-transfer spending in federal spending. In 2016, transfers to persons besides Social Security were roughly half of all non-defense federal spending.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

What to Watch on Jobs Day: Labor market should continue to improve, with or without pending tax cuts [feedly]

What to Watch on Jobs Day: Labor market should continue to improve, with or without pending tax cuts
http://www.epi.org/blog/what-to-watch-on-jobs-day-labor-market-should-continue-to-improve-with-or-without-pending-tax-cuts/

Tomorrow, the BLS will release the latest numbers on job creation and the labor market. Today, I'm going to take step back and provide some context for what we've seen so far this year, as we approach the 10th anniversary of the beginning of the Great Recession. I'm also going to provide some perspective on the tax bill wending its way through Congress, in light of steady progress in the labor market over the last several years. The bottom line is that (1) contrary to recent economic commentary surrounding the proposed tax cuts in Congress, it is not clear that we have reached genuine full employment yet and significant slack may still remain in the labor market , but (2) if we continue to see solid payroll employment growth in the months to come, we should expect to see continued strong progress in labor force participation, particularly among prime-age workers, and in wage growth—even in the absence of any fiscal stimulus from tax cuts. Any claims that these tax cuts, if they pass, will lead to significant improvement in the labor market or in wages need to be viewed in the context of an already steadily improving economy.

In January 2017, we released our autopilot economy tracker, as a way to set down key benchmarks for the U.S. economy. Think of it as providing a gauge of whether changes to policy are leaving any discernible mark on the economy's trajectory. We look at where several economic indicators were headed before the year started, and where they would be if those trends simply continued. Take, for example, the prime-age employment to population ratio (EPOP). In the figure below, you can see clearly the progress that has been made over the last several years, and the continuation of that trend through this year with no discernible uptick in the pace of recovery. Steady improvements in the prime-age EPOP since January have tracked our predictions of an economy on auto-pilot fairly well, and we should expect this trend to continue into next year.

EPOP 2015-2019
EPOP 1995-2019

The same goes for other indicators. Currently, the unemployment rate is beating expectations while nominal wage growth remains weaker than expected. However, as the economy continues to solidly add jobs, more would-be workers will be pulled back into the labor force. As that pool of potential workers who are currently jobless shrinks away, workers will have more bargaining power, which will translate into stronger wage growth. In turn, employers will begin investing more in labor-saving equipment and technology and we should see stronger productivity growth—which clears out even more room for wages to grow. This is the virtuous cycle we would like to see happen as the economy continues moving toward full employment, and there are clear signs that this process is beginning.

This analysis highlights the crucial importance of "high-pressure" labor markets for wage growth. An alternative visions says that it's the tax rate faced by corporations that is key to wage growth. The evidence for this tax-centric view of wage growth is weak, as my colleague Josh Bivens explains. The crux of his argument is that (1) productivity and wage growth have been significantly greater in periods with higher corporate tax rates, (2) there is no robust relationship between post-tax profit rates and productivity-enhancing investments, and (3) productivity growth is only a necessary, not sufficient, condition for wage growth (as we've seen in the last four decades when typical compensation has growth significantly slower than the rate of productivity growth). Furthermore, corporate tax cuts do nothing in terms of giving American workers more leverage and bargaining power to acquire a significant share of those higher profits in the form of wages. In short, the push to cut corporate tax rates is a distraction from what can boost wages quickly: a spell of genuine full employment.

This spell of genuine full employment might not be that far away, so, it's important that we recognize that stronger wage growth is on the horizon anyhow, and if these regressive tax cuts are passed, we cannot attribute that stronger wage growth and improvements in the labor market in general to said tax cuts.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Monday, December 4, 2017

Yet more on the terrible tax plan…



----
Yet more on the terrible tax plan… // Jared Bernstein | On the Economy
http://jaredbernsteinblog.com/yet-more-on-the-terrible-tax-plan/

Similar pieces wherein I'm trying to work out some of the longer term implications of what's happening with tax policy, the debt, and the forthcoming attack on spending programs that, you know, actually help some people.

Over at WaPo and TAP.

I've not forgotten that there's much else going on. I've got forthcoming pieces on the attack on financial market regulation, which, unless you're following this, goes deeper than you thought, and current economic conditions as a baseline against which to evaluate a bunch of silly claims that will soon be made about the impact of the tax plan on growth.


----

Read in my feedly.com

Enlighten Radio Podcasts:The Moose Turd Cafe -- KellyAnne Cocaine Opioid Extermination Camp Plan

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Enlighten Radio Podcasts
Post: The Moose Turd Cafe -- KellyAnne Cocaine Opioid Extermination Camp Plan
Link: http://podcasts.enlightenradio.org/2017/12/the-moose-turd-cafe-kellyanne-cocaine.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

Should-Read: David Anderson : Aetna, CVS and data thoughts : "This is a risk adjustment data gold mine... ...Aetna has ... [feedly]

Should-Read: David Anderson : Aetna, CVS and data thoughts : "This is a risk adjustment data gold mine... ...Aetna has ...
http://www.bradford-delong.com/2017/12/should-read-david-anderson-aetna-cvs-and-data-thoughtshttpswwwballoon-juicecom20171204aetna-cvs-and-data-t.html

Should-Read: David AndersonAetna, CVS and data thoughts: "This is a risk adjustment data gold mine...

...Aetna has a kick-ass data team. They have huge and deep data sets that they control. It is quite likely that a significant chunk of their risk adjusted covered lives in 2018 have shown up in some point in their data bases in the past decade. An individual who is now insured by Aetna Medicare Advantage in Texas may have had an amputation claim from Aetna Medicaid in Pennsylvania that is dated in 2009. That is valuable information to build and curate a risk adjustment optimization list. However there are always serious holes in the Aetna list.... This is where CVS comes in. There is a good chance that CVS has filled some prescriptions for people who do not show up in Aetna's data banks....

The other side... is that Aetna will have far more granular level information on their markets. This will influence plan design, it will influence marketing materials, it will influence whether or not Aetna enters or leaves a market or bids for certain contracts.

Finally, the biggest data bonanza from my point of view is the CVS non-prescription data that is tied to the loyalty card that almost everyone carries on their keychain. This should give a massive predictive edge to the Aetna data geeks. Let me share way too much personal.... If an insurer could see the non-prescription purchases tied to the customer loyalty card, they had an excellent idea of when my wife and I started trying for Kid #2. If this was an insurer that sought to be socially productive and useful, we could expect to get mailings and outreach calls on pre-natal and perhaps pre-conception health enhancers. If the insurer was run by cynical bastards and the time of the year was right, they might try to be enough of a pain in the ass to get us to switch insurers so that someone else could pay for labor and delivery....

This merger offers an incredibly rich vein of data that can be mined and minted. This makes a lot of sense to me without even thinking about how the entire pharmacy benefit management function is a messed up situation.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Larr Summers: Trump’s version of capitalism looks a lot like revenge — and it endangers our democracy [feedly]

Trump's version of capitalism looks a lot like revenge — and it endangers our democracy
http://larrysummers.com/2017/11/28/trumps-version-of-capitalism-looks-a-lot-like-revenge-and-it-endangers-our-democracy/

In response to the Carrier caper after the election last year, I decried the Trump administration's preference for what I called ad hoc deal capitalism. I noted that the practice was characteristic of developing countries and earlier times in the United States and that it was much less conducive to prosperity and freedom than capitalism based on the predictable rule of law.
Until last month, there had been fewer cases of deal capitalism than I had feared. But in the last month, policy has taken an ugly turn toward the selective and ad hoc use of government power — not to reward political friends but to punish political adversaries. Government rewards encourage cronyism and rent-seeking and waste public resources. Targeting adversaries may chill dissent and threaten democracy.

Two examples stand out.
First, the tax bill contains a provision directed at the investment income of large private university endowments. The revenue raised by such a move could be offset by raising the corporate tax rate from 20 percent to 20.03 percent, so the revenue impact is trivial. There might be a case for revisiting the taxation of nonprofits and looking at issues like unrelated business income, excessive accumulation, diversion of funds for private benefit or the perpetuation of privilege. But it is hard to see any principled tax policy case for focusing only on large private university endowments and not those of state universities, operas or hospitals.
As numerous congressional figures have made clear, however, the motivation behind the proposal is simple. They believe it is time to punish universities for their opposition to Republican positions and their advancement of what they see as "political correctness." I have some sympathy with concerns about ideological diversity at universities, but using the tax system to punish them is inconsistent with any reasonable principle of taxation and with the idea of a free society. If sectors of our society come to think that they cannot speak out on issues of public concern for fear of retribution, our democracy will be traduced.
Second, the targeting by the Justice Department of the proposed AT&T-Time Warner merger invites suspicion of selective prosecution. There are, to be sure, legitimate arguments for attacking vertical combinations of the type this deal represents, and many across the political spectrum have called for enhanced antitrust enforcement. But, again, the circumstances here are suspicious.
In every other area of public policy, the administration has come down on the side of more freedom for businesses to do as they wish and reliance on market forces rather than on regulatory discipline. Indeed, the administration's position on net neutrality only makes sense if one is relatively unconcerned with the possibility of carriers like AT&T having monopoly power. Moreover, the head of the antitrust division, Makan Delrahim, was recently of the view that the merger was not problematic. And rumors that President Trump's anger with CNN could affect the merger have been pervasive, with Trump taking the extraordinary step of publicly commenting on Justice Department enforcement actions.
This kind of thing is not without precedent. President Richard Nixon's enemies list was intended in part to influence policy toward his adversaries. But I believe that the Trump administration's selective economic punishment of political opponents is a targeted attack on our democratic values, and I hope the business community, and at least a few Republicans in Congress, will speak out

 -- via my feedly newsfeed