Friday, August 5, 2016

Re: [socialist-econ] Triple crisis: The Economics of Political Change in Developed Countries [feedly]

This is a very important article that should be shared widely.  It is an excellent argument for government intervention in labor markets and the economy more broadly to raise wages.  


Sent from my iPad

On Aug 5, 2016, at 6:36 AM, John Case <jcase4218@gmail.com> wrote:

The Economics of Political Change in Developed Countries
http://triplecrisis.com/the-economics-of-political-change-in-developed-countries/

Jayati Ghosh

Across the world, people have been watching recent political changes in developed countries with a mixture of bemusement and shock. From the recent anointment of Donald Trump as the Republican candidate for US President, to the rise and spread of blatantly racist anti-immigration political parties and movements in Europe, it is clear that there are tectonic shifts under way in the political discourse and practice in these countries. As these changes have gone from the unthinkable to the depressingly predictable, there are increasingly desperate attempts to understand what is driving them. This is especially the case because – despite all the talk of a shift in global power to some large "emerging nations" – what happens in the developed countries still matters hugely in international relations and to all of us in the rest of the world.

It is now obvious that increasing inequality, stagnant real incomes of working people and the increasing material fragility of daily life have all played roles in creating a strong sense of dissatisfaction among ordinary people in the rich countries. While even the poor amongst them still continue to be hugely better off than the vast majority of people in the developing world, their own perceptions are quite different, and they increasingly see themselves as the victims of globalisation.

But while this is increasingly recognised, the full extent of recent economic trends is probably less well known. A new report from the McKinsey Global Institute ("Poorer Than Their Parents? Flat or falling incomes in advanced economies", July 2016) brings out in detail how the past decade in particular has been significantly worse for many people in the developed world.

The report is based on a study of income distribution data from 25 developed countries; a detailed dataset with more information on 350,000 people from France, Italy and the United States and the UK; and a survey of 6,000 people from France, the United Kingdom and the United States that also checked for perceptions about the evolution of their incomes.

The results are probably not surprising in terms of the basic trends identified, but the sheer extent of the change and the deterioration in incomes still comes as a surprise. In 25 advanced economies, between 65 and 70 percent of households (amounting to around 540- 580 million people) were in segments of the income that experienced flat or falling incomes between 2005 and 2014. By contrast, in the previous period between 1993 and 2005, less than 2 percent (fewer than ten million people) faced flat or falling incomes.

The situation was much worse in particular countries. In Italy, a whopping 97 per cent of the population had stagnant or declining real incomes between 2005 and 2014, while the ratios were 81 per cent for the United States and 70 per cent in the United Kingdom. This refers to market incomes, and it is true that government tax and transfer policies can change the final disposable income of households, in some cases improving it. Indeed, for the 25 countries taken together, only 20-25 per cent experienced flat or falling disposable incomes. In the US, government taxes and transfers turned a decline in market incomes for 81 percent of households into an increase in disposable income for nearly all of them.

Similarly, government policies to intervene in labour markets also made a difference. In Sweden, the government intervened with measures designed to preserve jobs, so market incomes fell or were flat for only 20 percent, while tax and transfer policies ensured that disposable income advanced for almost everyone. But in most of the countries examined in the study, government policies were not sufficient to prevent stagnant or declining incomes 2 for a significant proportion of the population, and labour market trends contributed to feelings of insecurity among workers everywhere.

While these changes were evident across the board, the worst affected were less educated workers, and particularly the younger ones among them, as well as women, especially single mothers. The report notes that today's younger generation in the advanced countries is at real risk of ending up poorer than their parents, and in any case already faces much more insecure working conditions.

This material reality is actually quite accurately reflected in popular perceptions. A survey conducted in 2015 of British, French and US citizens confirmed this, as approximately 40 per cent of those surveyed felt that their economic positions had deteriorated. Interestingly it was also such people, as well as those who did not expect the situation to improve for the next generation, who felt most negatively about both trade and migration. More than half of this group agreed with the statement, "The influx of foreign goods and services is leading to domestic job losses," compared with 29 per cent of those who were advancing or neutral. They were also twice as likely to agree with the statement, "Legal immigrants are ruining the culture and cohesiveness in our society," compared to those advancing or neutral. The survey also found that those whose incomes were not improving and who were not hopeful about the future were more likely in France to support political parties such as Front National and in Britain to support Brexit.

One major driver of stagnant worker incomes has been the combination of labour market developments and public policies that have resulted in declining wage shares of national income. The report notes that from 1970 to 2014 – with the brief exception of a spike during the 1973–74 oil crisis – the average wage share across the 6 countries studied in depth (United States, United Kingdom, France, Italy, the Netherlands and Sweden) fell by 5 percentage points. In the most extreme case of the United Kingdom, it declined by 13 percentage points. These declines in wage shares occurred despite increases in labour productivity, as the productivity gains were either grabbed by employers or passed on in the form of lower prices to maintain external competitiveness.

Such declining wage shares are commonly seen to be the result of globalisation and technological changes that have led to changing patterns of demand for low-skill and medium-skill workers. But even here, it is evident that state policies and institutional relations in the labour market matter. In Sweden, where 68 percent of workers are union members and the government has in place policies that enforce contracts that protect both wage rates and hours worked, the median household received a greater share of output that went to wages, and even got more of the gains from aggregate income growth than households in the top and bottom income deciles over the 2005–14 period.

By contrast, countries that have encouraged the growth of part-time and temporary contracts experienced bigger declines in wage shares. Once again, this is especially adverse for the young. According to European Union official data, more than 40 per cent of workers aged between 15 and 25 years in the 28 countries of the EU have such insecure and low- paying contracts, while the proportion is more than half for the 18 countries in the Eurozone, 58 per cent in France and 65 per cent in Spain. This is obviously a concern for the young people who have to experience this, but it is as much a source of unhappiness and anger for their parents who worry for the future of their children.

In the meantime, they can all observe the counterpart in terms of rising profit shares in many of these rich countries. Economic processes and government policies increasingly appear to favour plutocratic tendencies. In the United States, for example, post-tax profits of firms in the period 2010-14 reached more than 10.1 per cent of GDP, a level last reached in 1929 just before the Great Depression. Ironically, in the US this is apparently favouring the political rise of one of the biggest beneficiaries of this process, Donald Trump who is himself emblematic of such plutocracy.

If economic policies do not change dramatically to favour more good quality employment and better labour market outcomes through co-ordinated fiscal expansions, to lift growth in more inclusive ways, things are likely to get even worse. The report projects that even if the previous high-growth trajectory is resumed (an unlikely prospect) at least 30-40 per cent of households would not get income gains over the next decade, especially if technological changes like more automation accelerate. And if the slow growth conditions of 2005–12 persist, the proportion of households experiencing flat or falling incomes could go to as much as 70-80 per cent by 2025.

The unpleasant and even terrifying political fallout of such outcomes is now only too evident. How much more will it take for political leaders to recognise the need for a move away from business as usual to radical change in economic policies?

Triple Crisis welcomes your comments. Please share your thoughts below.

Triple Crisis is published by


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

--
You received this message because you are subscribed to the Google Groups "Socialist Economics" group.
To unsubscribe from this group and stop receiving emails from it, send an email to socialist-economics+unsubscribe@googlegroups.com.
To post to this group, send email to socialist-economics@googlegroups.com.
Visit this group at https://groups.google.com/group/socialist-economics.
To view this discussion on the web visit https://groups.google.com/d/msgid/socialist-economics/CADH2idKw%2BpJt3qJ-U7oGp6prw3eT9bq_8-n3%2BGXyq1Rgn8T-WQ%40mail.gmail.com.
For more options, visit https://groups.google.com/d/optout.

Triple crisis: The Economics of Political Change in Developed Countries [feedly]

The Economics of Political Change in Developed Countries
http://triplecrisis.com/the-economics-of-political-change-in-developed-countries/

Jayati Ghosh

Across the world, people have been watching recent political changes in developed countries with a mixture of bemusement and shock. From the recent anointment of Donald Trump as the Republican candidate for US President, to the rise and spread of blatantly racist anti-immigration political parties and movements in Europe, it is clear that there are tectonic shifts under way in the political discourse and practice in these countries. As these changes have gone from the unthinkable to the depressingly predictable, there are increasingly desperate attempts to understand what is driving them. This is especially the case because – despite all the talk of a shift in global power to some large "emerging nations" – what happens in the developed countries still matters hugely in international relations and to all of us in the rest of the world.

It is now obvious that increasing inequality, stagnant real incomes of working people and the increasing material fragility of daily life have all played roles in creating a strong sense of dissatisfaction among ordinary people in the rich countries. While even the poor amongst them still continue to be hugely better off than the vast majority of people in the developing world, their own perceptions are quite different, and they increasingly see themselves as the victims of globalisation.

But while this is increasingly recognised, the full extent of recent economic trends is probably less well known. A new report from the McKinsey Global Institute ("Poorer Than Their Parents? Flat or falling incomes in advanced economies", July 2016) brings out in detail how the past decade in particular has been significantly worse for many people in the developed world.

The report is based on a study of income distribution data from 25 developed countries; a detailed dataset with more information on 350,000 people from France, Italy and the United States and the UK; and a survey of 6,000 people from France, the United Kingdom and the United States that also checked for perceptions about the evolution of their incomes.

The results are probably not surprising in terms of the basic trends identified, but the sheer extent of the change and the deterioration in incomes still comes as a surprise. In 25 advanced economies, between 65 and 70 percent of households (amounting to around 540- 580 million people) were in segments of the income that experienced flat or falling incomes between 2005 and 2014. By contrast, in the previous period between 1993 and 2005, less than 2 percent (fewer than ten million people) faced flat or falling incomes.

The situation was much worse in particular countries. In Italy, a whopping 97 per cent of the population had stagnant or declining real incomes between 2005 and 2014, while the ratios were 81 per cent for the United States and 70 per cent in the United Kingdom. This refers to market incomes, and it is true that government tax and transfer policies can change the final disposable income of households, in some cases improving it. Indeed, for the 25 countries taken together, only 20-25 per cent experienced flat or falling disposable incomes. In the US, government taxes and transfers turned a decline in market incomes for 81 percent of households into an increase in disposable income for nearly all of them.

Similarly, government policies to intervene in labour markets also made a difference. In Sweden, the government intervened with measures designed to preserve jobs, so market incomes fell or were flat for only 20 percent, while tax and transfer policies ensured that disposable income advanced for almost everyone. But in most of the countries examined in the study, government policies were not sufficient to prevent stagnant or declining incomes 2 for a significant proportion of the population, and labour market trends contributed to feelings of insecurity among workers everywhere.

While these changes were evident across the board, the worst affected were less educated workers, and particularly the younger ones among them, as well as women, especially single mothers. The report notes that today's younger generation in the advanced countries is at real risk of ending up poorer than their parents, and in any case already faces much more insecure working conditions.

This material reality is actually quite accurately reflected in popular perceptions. A survey conducted in 2015 of British, French and US citizens confirmed this, as approximately 40 per cent of those surveyed felt that their economic positions had deteriorated. Interestingly it was also such people, as well as those who did not expect the situation to improve for the next generation, who felt most negatively about both trade and migration. More than half of this group agreed with the statement, "The influx of foreign goods and services is leading to domestic job losses," compared with 29 per cent of those who were advancing or neutral. They were also twice as likely to agree with the statement, "Legal immigrants are ruining the culture and cohesiveness in our society," compared to those advancing or neutral. The survey also found that those whose incomes were not improving and who were not hopeful about the future were more likely in France to support political parties such as Front National and in Britain to support Brexit.

One major driver of stagnant worker incomes has been the combination of labour market developments and public policies that have resulted in declining wage shares of national income. The report notes that from 1970 to 2014 – with the brief exception of a spike during the 1973–74 oil crisis – the average wage share across the 6 countries studied in depth (United States, United Kingdom, France, Italy, the Netherlands and Sweden) fell by 5 percentage points. In the most extreme case of the United Kingdom, it declined by 13 percentage points. These declines in wage shares occurred despite increases in labour productivity, as the productivity gains were either grabbed by employers or passed on in the form of lower prices to maintain external competitiveness.

Such declining wage shares are commonly seen to be the result of globalisation and technological changes that have led to changing patterns of demand for low-skill and medium-skill workers. But even here, it is evident that state policies and institutional relations in the labour market matter. In Sweden, where 68 percent of workers are union members and the government has in place policies that enforce contracts that protect both wage rates and hours worked, the median household received a greater share of output that went to wages, and even got more of the gains from aggregate income growth than households in the top and bottom income deciles over the 2005–14 period.

By contrast, countries that have encouraged the growth of part-time and temporary contracts experienced bigger declines in wage shares. Once again, this is especially adverse for the young. According to European Union official data, more than 40 per cent of workers aged between 15 and 25 years in the 28 countries of the EU have such insecure and low- paying contracts, while the proportion is more than half for the 18 countries in the Eurozone, 58 per cent in France and 65 per cent in Spain. This is obviously a concern for the young people who have to experience this, but it is as much a source of unhappiness and anger for their parents who worry for the future of their children.

In the meantime, they can all observe the counterpart in terms of rising profit shares in many of these rich countries. Economic processes and government policies increasingly appear to favour plutocratic tendencies. In the United States, for example, post-tax profits of firms in the period 2010-14 reached more than 10.1 per cent of GDP, a level last reached in 1929 just before the Great Depression. Ironically, in the US this is apparently favouring the political rise of one of the biggest beneficiaries of this process, Donald Trump who is himself emblematic of such plutocracy.

If economic policies do not change dramatically to favour more good quality employment and better labour market outcomes through co-ordinated fiscal expansions, to lift growth in more inclusive ways, things are likely to get even worse. The report projects that even if the previous high-growth trajectory is resumed (an unlikely prospect) at least 30-40 per cent of households would not get income gains over the next decade, especially if technological changes like more automation accelerate. And if the slow growth conditions of 2005–12 persist, the proportion of households experiencing flat or falling incomes could go to as much as 70-80 per cent by 2025.

The unpleasant and even terrifying political fallout of such outcomes is now only too evident. How much more will it take for political leaders to recognise the need for a move away from business as usual to radical change in economic policies?

Triple Crisis welcomes your comments. Please share your thoughts below.

Triple Crisis is published by


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Thursday, August 4, 2016

Carlotta Perez Remarks on TECHNOLOGICAL REVOLUTIONS AND POLITICAL CHOICES

Carlota Perez is a most interesting Venezuelan Schumpeterian, on the left wing of his economic descendants, and a long waver. She researches the concept of Techno-Economic paradigm shifts and the theory of great surges, a further development of Schumpeter's work on Kondratieff waves. In 2012 she was awarded the Silver Kondratieff Medal by the International N. D. Kondratieff Foundation.  For you left wing historical reference hunters, Kondratieff was Lenin's favorite economist, and most influential in the drafting and argumentation for the New Economic Program -- later renounced and exterminated, along with Kondratiev, by Stalin, of course, but resurrected by Deng Chou Peng.

The following remarks were contracted by Shell Oil Corp as an honorarium for a presentation she did to their leadership.


A VIEW FROM PROFESSOR CARLOTA PEREZ

Since the industrial revolution, each subsequent technological revolution has gone through two different periods.

The first is installation, when unfettered markets in a financial frenzy set up a huge market experiment to define the products and the companies that will be the winners for the future; when the new infrastructures (canals, railways and telegraph, ports and steamships, highways and electricity or internet) are installed; and when the new paradigm is learned and adopted by companies and people. It is a time of 'creative destruction' as the Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter rightly defined it. But the process often leads to a major bubble or two and can end in a huge financial crash. The recessions that follow reveal how much 'destruction' had gone on under the shine of the boom, including how much inequality resulted from the success of the relatively few involved in the bubble prosperity. It is by coming out of those recessions that past periods of golden age prosperities have been unleashed – bringing the second period of each technological revolution. They require government involvement to tilt the playing field in a direction that will reduce the risk for all and increase profitability through generating synergies in common suppliers, skills, knowledge, and consumer requirements. This is possible because each of the installed revolutions provides an enormous potential for transforming the whole economy and changing lifestyles in many possible directions. 


For example, the mass production revolution of the 20th century was shaped very differently by Nazi Germany, the Soviet Union, and the Western democracies. The latter provided clear directions for innovation to serve suburbanisation, European reconstruction, and the Cold War. What became the all-electric home with multiple appliances for cooking, freezing, and entertainment, with innumerable plastic objects, often meant for disposability, and a car at the door gave a clear direction for innovation and a well-defined shape to demand. 

Yet this was not achieved by markets alone but by a favorable context for markets to act. In the US and Europe, for example, that context included the welfare state, the consumer society, unemployment insurance (for uninterrupted payment of consumer credit), pensions (to safely spend monthly incomes without worrying about old age), and a progressive tax system able to fund the welfare state, the Cold War, massive state employment, education and health services, roads, and so on. And, while the income of public servants went into increasing demand, the publicly provided services freed income for consumption. 

The world is now in a similar historical moment requiring equally bold and systemic institutional and policy changes to harness the true potential offered by the digital and IT revolution of the last two decades and to give a direction to innovation. It is not to be any direction but one that has roots in the nature of the new technologies and in the problems inherited from the old ones. That direction is "green growth," widely understood as increasing the proportion of services and intangibles in GDP, world trade, and in lifestyles. Green growth involves reducing the amount of materials and energy in tangible products, decreasing or eliminating waste through reuse and recycling in the circular economy, making products really durable while moving to rental and maintenance, including 3D printing of parts for upgrading, and changing the ideal of a good life to one that involves fewer material goods, with an emphasis on exercise, creativity, preventive health care, unprocessed food (preferably grown nearby), community, communications activities, computer or smart phone-based music, films, books, education through a combination of online courses and face-toface interactions, experiential entertainment, and so forth. All this requires a massive shift to policies of indirect energy conservation, contributing to reduce carbon emissions. 

Most importantly, it makes it possible for the people of the whole world to aspire to a good life that is viable on our single planet. In addition to this change in consumer behavior, many profound changes also have to take place in manufacturing, power generation, land use, and other aspects of production in order to make the best of the IT revolution. In the current playing field, such a transformation cannot be achieved by markets alone. The field has to be tilted by state action, and this time also at the global level. 

Fortunately the transition to green growth has already begun to happen. The upper and educated layers of the population – together with many of the young –are adopting the ICT-intensive mode of living, together with health, exercise, adventure and concerts rather than purchasing commodities as entertainment. Imitation will follow as has happened historically – but it may not happen quickly or at an equal rate everywhere. 

Each technological revolution provides a new space of the possible that is then shaped by socio-political choice in the deployment period. That is the choice the world has ahead now. We can continue to a "gilded age" with financial markets and the military shaping the playing field, and with growing inequality and environmental degradation for the new millions who will inhabit our planet. Or we can create policies that encourage green growth, bringing social and environmental sustainability across the world with a rising standard of living even for the poorest. It is a task equivalent to what the welfare state and the new international institutions (World Bank, IMF, etc.) did for the post-war boom in the advanced countries of the West. It will require an equivalent amount of imagination and a huge dose of bold, collaborative political and business leadership


John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV

The Winners and Losers Radio Show
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Tuesday, August 2, 2016

Baker: Homeownership Drop is Bad News, but Not for the Reason You Think [feedly]

Homeownership Drop is Bad News, but Not for the Reason You Think
http://cepr.net/publications/op-eds-columns/homeownership-drop-is-bad-news-but-not-for-the-reason-you-think

The homeownership rate fell again in the second quarter of 2016, hitting the lowest rate in more than 50 years, more than 6 full percentage points below the peak bubble years. This is both good news and bad news.

It is good news because homeownership is not always good for everyone at all points in their lives. The building, banking and real estate industry have worked hard to make renting seem un-American. While homeownership can be a useful way for families to accumulate wealth, it's not generally advisable for people not in a stable employment and family situation.

The transaction costs associated with buying and selling a home are roughly 10 percent of the sales price, which comes to almost $25,000 for a typical home. This is a lot of money to throw away for someone who has to move after a year or two because of losing a job or a family break-up. Of course the lost money to the homeowner is income for bankers and realtors.

The other reason it might be a good thing to see a declining homeownership rate is that it seems some markets are again rising into bubble territory. The bottom third by sales price of homes in Miami saw a 55.6 percent price increase over the last three years. By contrast, rents have risen just 10.4 percent. In Chicago the price of the bottom third of homes increased by 40.7 percent in the last three years, while rents rose by 6.9 percent.

There are several other cities in which prices in the less expensive segment of the market are rising precipitously. It would be a good thing if moderate income families didn't buy into bubble inflated markets yet again.

The bad side is: The main reason people are not buying homes does not have to do with them having better insight into the nature of the housing market. According to the Census Bureau, earnings for the median male worker still have not recovered to their pre-recession level, while earnings for women are just trivially higher more than seven years later. Furthermore, the employment rate for prime age workers (ages 25 to 54) is still down by almost three percentage points from the pre-recession level.

If families were deciding that it was better to put their money elsewhere rather than buy a home we would be seeing more rapid growth in their holdings of other financial assets. We in fact see the opposite. The Federal Reserve Board's 2013 Survey of Consumer Finance, the most recent one available, shows that assets outside of housing are down sharply from pre-recession levels for all age brackets. Clearly people are not opting to put their money elsewhere; they just don't have the money.

This is clearly a bad story. It's made worse by the fact that the biggest drops in homeownership are for African-Americans, who are again being hardest hit by a weak economy. It will be good if families can make informed decisions between renting and owning, but it will be even better when more of them actually have this choice.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Free trade in moral hypocrisy [feedly]

I sympathize with the outrage at phonies about the losers in trade, but the article is ruined for me by the abuse of the term "neoliberalism", which, I submit means absolutely nothing except on left left pubs where it is just a fig leaf for not having to say the word "capitalism" too many times. What is a Non-neo-liberal position on trade, for example?


Jeff Faux: EPI:  Free trade in moral hypocrisy

A version of this article appeared in the Globalist.

U.S. trade policy of the last 20 years, if not dead, is on life- support. The economic case for the series of neoliberal trade deals since the North American Free Trade Agreement has collapsed in the wake of job losses, lower wages and shrinking opportunities for American workers. Voters are hostile, and both candidates for President oppose the latest proposed trade pact—the Trans Pacific Partnership.

But neoliberal trade deals have brought enormous profits to America's multinational corporate investors. So, big business lobbyists and their champions in the Congress and the Administration are organizing to pass the TPP in the post-election lame duck session—regardless of who wins the election.

With their economic arguments discredited, they are now draping these trade and investment pacts with a mantle of moral superiority. American workers who complain are now told that they should be ashamed of themselves. Why? Because off-shoring their jobs helps workers in other counties who are even poorer.

Paul Krugman tells his New York Times readers that they should support "open world markets…mainly because market access is so important to poor countries."

Read more


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Worst recovery in post-war era largely explained by cuts in government spending

Worst recovery in post-war era largely explained by cuts in government spending

Re: [socialist-econ] Are wealth and power the same?

With Flanders being autonomous and with such high per capita income I wonder how that wealth is generated and, more importantly to me, how it is distributed.

Sent from my iPad

On Aug 2, 2016, at 4:12 AM, John Case <jcase4218@gmail.com> wrote:

http://econospeak.blogspot.com/2016/08/wealth-and-power-does-one-necessarily.html?m=1

--
You received this message because you are subscribed to the Google Groups "Socialist Economics" group.
To unsubscribe from this group and stop receiving emails from it, send an email to socialist-economics+unsubscribe@googlegroups.com.
To post to this group, send email to socialist-economics@googlegroups.com.
Visit this group at https://groups.google.com/group/socialist-economics.
To view this discussion on the web visit https://groups.google.com/d/msgid/socialist-economics/CADH2idKHZL_MUnXnR63YxDZs5%2BqwUTsZxJFHjAMVGcz3EDCrgQ%40mail.gmail.com.
For more options, visit https://groups.google.com/d/optout.