Tuesday, July 17, 2018

Recovery Radio:Recovery Radio: Recovery Ready Communities

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Recovery Radio
Post: Recovery Radio: Recovery Ready Communities
Link: http://recovery.enlightenradio.org/2018/07/recovery-radio-recovery-ready.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

Monday, July 16, 2018

Recovery Radio:Recovery radio -- Medically assisted Treatment

John Case has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Recovery Radio
Post: Recovery radio -- Medically assisted Treatment
Link: http://recovery.enlightenradio.org/2018/07/recovery-radio-medically-assisted.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

The Real Driver of Health Care Spending


Edward M Murphy 

via Portside

An inefficiency gap is boosting costs — and profits

, Khalil Bendib / Other Words

 

THE HEALTH CARE DEBATES that occurred in Washington over the past year were largely irrelevant to what's happening in the health care marketplace. Republicans couldn't repeal the Affordable Care Act but they made some changes that weakened it. Those changes will increase insurance premiums in the individual market but they do nothing to address the most significant trends that are evolving across the system. To understand the important trends, one must look elsewhere.

In March, three researchers from the Harvard T. H. Chan School of Public Health published a study in JAMA analyzing the well-known reality that the United States spends dramatically more on health care than other wealthy countries. They compared the US, where health care consumes 17.8 per cent of gross domestic product, to 10 comparable nations where the mean expenditure is 11.5 percent. Despite spending much less, the other countries provide health insurance to their entire populations and have outcomes equal to or better than ours. The researchers found that this inefficiency gap is primarily driven by two characteristics of the US system: the high cost of pharmaceuticals and inordinate administrative expenses.

For example, annual per capita pharmaceutical expenditure in the US is $1,443 as compared to an average of $749 in the 10 other countries. Our administrative costs consume 8 percent of total spending as compared to a range of 1 to 3 percent elsewhere. No one else is close on either of these measures.

The high administrative spending derives in large part from the fact that 55 percent of the people in the US are covered by private health insurers who embed their own billing requirements, expenses, and profit into the system. The next highest country in this regard is Germany, where 10.8 percent of the population is covered by private insurers. In many countries, there are no such middlemen.

Coincidentally, when the JAMA study was published, the large publicly traded health care companies that dominate the US market had just finished disclosing their 2017 financial results. Examining those results provides additional insight into the economic forces that make our system so expensive and inefficient. The scale of the money involved is sometimes hard to grasp. The largest health care corporations, those included in the S&P 500, had almost $2 trillion in revenue last year. (Table 1)

Most of these enormous companies are engaged in one of two businesses: they're either selling drugs or they're selling health insurance. The excess costs reported by the Harvard researchers serve mainly to support the revenue of the companies in those fields.

The 2017 reporting of corporate profits was complicated by the passage of the new tax bill. But most companies also reported "adjusted net income," which shows their normalized profits after accounting for the one-time impact of the tax law. The chart below (Table 2) uses the adjusted numbers to show the largest annual profits among S&P health care companies.

Health insurers such as United Health and retailers such as CVS have enormous revenue and impressive profits but, when profit is measured as a percentage of revenue, they can't compete with biotech and pharma. The highest relative profitability, using the same reported adjusted results, is in the chart below. (Table 3)

These profit margins show that there are many situations where between a third and a half of every dollar spent on a prescription drug falls to the bottom line of the of the company that made it. This profit derives in large part from the enormous difference in drug prices in the US versus other countries where such prices are more effectively controlled.

The high administrative cost of the US system stems from the large portion of the market dominated by insurance companies looking to maximize their profits.  Notwithstanding many news stories about turmoil in the insurance markets, 2017 was a banner year for the largest health insurers. The big players all had significant increases in annual profitability in 2017.

Note that Humana did not report "adjusted" numbers even though its profit was swollen by unusual events. A major distortion was a huge break-up fee the company received from a failed merger. That accounted for approximately $630 million in after-tax profit. Even discounting that, it was a very good year.

The revenue and profitability of these corporations support the proposition that high pharmaceutical prices and insurance-related administrative costs account for much of the extraordinary expense of our system. US health policy, or the absence thereof, has enabled these businesses annually to drive costs up for the benefit of their bottom line. That effect will continue. Not surprisingly, the big health care companies are developing new strategies to enhance their businesses and drive their profits going forward.

The term now heard often among health care giants is "vertical integration," which means combining upstream suppliers with downstream buyers to control the flow of business. If this strategy persists, health care delivery will evolve significantly although it is unlikely to become less expensive. The most prominent current example of  vertical integration is the planned $68 billion acquisition of Aetna by CVS.

How would these companies work together? A Wall Street analyst recently described the vision as a way to "identify high risk patients and preemptively get them into a Minute Clinic." Thus, your health insurer could send you to a local store for diagnosis, treatment, drugs, and anything else you might need from the shelves. This will keep even more of the health care dollar under their control.

Similarly, Cigna is in the process of acquiring Express Scripts, a huge pharmacy benefits manager, for $54 billion, another attempt to bring more services under one roof. The combined company would have annual revenue of $142 billion and, presumably, enough leverage with drug companies to improve profits although not necessarily to lower costs to patients. United Health, a leader of vertical integration, previously bought a pharmacy benefit manager but co-pays and deductibles for its patients have continued to climb. United has aggressively acquired physician practices in recent years and is now in the process of buying DaVita Medical Group, which operates nearly 300 clinics and outpatient surgical centers.

More striking are reports of a potential but unsigned merger of Walmart and Humana, a combined company that would have revenue of $550 billion. Walmart is a large operator of retail pharmacies inside its stores and the logic is similar to the Aetna-CVS deal. Humana, a huge insurer, is separately in the process of acquiring a large home health business from Kindred so this could represent yet another level of vertical integration.

If this course continues, the health care system will evolve quickly, giving fewer and larger companies even more market leverage. Integration of this kind benefits the large corporations that initiate it but there is no evidence it will lead to lower costs, improved access, or enhanced quality. These changes are driven by highly focused corporate financial interests and are occurring without reference to public policy. That's because there is no coherent public policy to guide these changes.

On May 11, President Trump made a long-awaited speech to reveal what he described as "the most sweeping action in history to lower the price of prescription drugs for the American people." His typically firebrand language struck at "drug makers, insurance companies, distributors, pharmacy benefit managers, and many others" who contributed to "this incredible abuse." His attack seemed to target the large public companies that have benefited from the abuse. Unsurprisingly, his speech did not include specifics. His staff then released tepid policy details, which immediately generated a significant upward spike in the biotech stock index as well as the stock prices of other large health care companies. For all the presidential bombast, investors saw Trump's policy for what it is: indifference to the current path and no threat to high prices.

It is not in the interest of huge profit-making corporations to restrain the overall cost of the US health care system. In fact, their interest is served by driving health care expenditures higher. When combined with the spending analysis provided by researchers, the financial data disclosed by public corporations point to a path that the country must follow to make our system more coherent and less costly. Any progress will require driving down pharmaceutical pricing and reducing administrative costs imposed by middlemen. We are not doing that yet but, ultimately, we must.

Edward M. Murphy worked in state government from 1979-1995, serving as the commissioner of the Department of Youth Services, commissioner of the Department of Mental Health, and executive director of the Health and Educational Facilities Authority. He recently retired as CEO and chairman of one of the country's largest providers of services to people with disabilities. The author is grateful for the assistance of Zachary Curtis in gathering financial information for this article. Curtis graduated in May from the business school at Bridgewater State University where Murphy is a trustee



--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Saturday, July 14, 2018

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF TRUMP’S TRADE WAR

ERKELEY – US President Donald Trump's phony, blowhard's trade war just got real.

THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF TRUMP'S TRADE WAR

Jul 12, 2018  asks why the effect of escalating protectionism on investment and financial markets has been so limited.

10Add to Bookmarks

The steel and aluminum tariffs that the Trump administration imposed at the beginning of June were important mainly for their symbolic value, not for their real economic impact. While the tariffs signified that the United States was no longer playing by the rules of the world trading system, they targeted just $45 billion of imports, less than 0.25% of GDP in an $18.5 trillion US economy.

On July 6, however, an additional 25% tariff on $34 billion of Chinese exports went into effect, and China retaliated against an equivalent volume of US exports. An angry Trump has ordered the US trade representative to draw up a list of additional Chinese goods, worth more than $400 billion, that could be taxed, and China again vowed to retaliate. Trump has also threatened to impose tariffs on $350 billion worth of imported motor vehicles and parts. If he does, the European Union and others could retaliate against an equal amount of US exports.

We are now talking about real money: nearly $1 trillion of US imports and an equivalent amount of US export sales and foreign investments.

The mystery is why the economic and financial fallout from this escalation has been so limited. The US economy is humming along. The Purchasing Managers' Index was up again in June. Wall Street has wobbled, but there has been nothing resembling its sharp negative reaction to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930. Emerging markets have suffered capital outflows and currency weakness, but this is more a consequence of Federal Reserve interest-rate hikes than of any announcements emanating from the White House.

There are three possible explanations. First, purchasing managers and stock market investors may be betting that sanity will yet prevail. They may be hoping that Trump's threats are just bluster, or that the objections of the US Chamber of Commerce and other business groups will ultimately register.1

Second, the markets may be betting that Trump is right when he says that trade wars are easy to win. Other countries that depend on exports to the US may conclude that it is in their interest to back down. In early July, the European Commission was reportedly contemplating a tariff-cutting deal to address Trump's complaint that the EU taxes American cars at four times the rate the US taxes European sedans.But this ignores the fact that Trump's tariff talk is wildly popular with his base. One recent poll found that 66% of Republican voters backed Trump's threatened tariffs against China. Trump ran in 2016 on a protectionist vow that he would no longer allow other countries to "take advantage" of the US. His voters expect him to deliver on that promise, and he knows it.

But China shows no willingness to buckle under US pressure. Canada, that politest of countries, is similarly unwilling to be bullied; it has retaliated with 25% tariffs on $12 billion of US goods. And the EU would contemplate concessions only if the US offers some in return – such as eliminating its prohibitive tariffs on imported light pickup trucks and vans – and only if other exporters like Japan and South Korea go along.

Third, it could be that the macroeconomic effects of even the full panoply of US tariffs, together with foreign retaliation, are relatively small. Leading models of the US economy, in particular, imply that a 10% increase in the cost of imported goods will lead to a one-time increase in inflation of at most 0.7%.

This is simply the law of iterated fractions at work. Imports are 15% of US GDP. Multiply 0.15 by 0.10 (the hypothesized tariff rate), and you get 1.5%. Allow for some substitution away from more expensive imported goods, and the number drops below 1%. And if growth slows because of the higher cost of imported intermediate inputs, the Fed can offset this by raising interest rates more slowly. Foreign central banks can do likewise.

Still, one worries, because the standard economic models are notoriously bad at capturing the macroeconomic effects of uncertainty, which trade wars create with a vengeance. Investment plans are made in advance, so it may take, say, a year for the impact of that uncertainty to materialize – as was the case in the United Kingdom following the 2016 Brexit referendum. Taxing intermediate inputs will hurt efficiency, while shifting resources away from dynamic high-tech sectors in favor of old-line manufacturing will depress productivity growth, with further negative implications for investment. And these are outcomes that the Fed cannot easily offset.

So, for those who observe that the economic and financial fallout from Trump's trade war has been surprisingly small, the best response is: just wait



--
John Case
Harpers Ferry, WV
Sign UP HERE to get the Weekly Program Notes.

Friday, July 13, 2018

In Latest ACA Sabotage, Administration Nearly Eliminates Marketplace Enrollment Assistance Funds [feedly]

In Latest ACA Sabotage, Administration Nearly Eliminates Marketplace Enrollment Assistance Funds
https://www.cbpp.org/blog/in-latest-aca-sabotage-administration-nearly-eliminates-marketplace-enrollment-assistance-funds

The Trump Administration this week slashed funding for consumer enrollment assistance and outreach through the Affordable Care Act (ACA) navigator program. The funding cuts, and other changes to the program, will reduce access to crucial assistance that helps consumers make informed decisions about their insurance and sign up for and maintain comprehensive coverage – yet another in the Administration's efforts to weaken the ACA.

The latest cut reduces funding for the navigator program to just $10 million for the 34 states whose ACA marketplaces are facilitated by the federal government. Combined with the large cut last year, navigator funding has now fallen more than 80 percent from its 2016 level.

Navigators raise awareness about the availability of ACA coverage and subsidies, help vulnerable and hard-to-reach communities complete complex eligibility and enrollment processes, assist people with grievances, and connect people to other resources, such as tax experts, as needed.

The Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) makes three flawed arguments to justify slashing navigator funding.

  • First, it claims that the need for navigators has "diminished" as the ACA marketplaces have become more visible and familiar. In fact, outreach remains critical in building awareness among people who could benefit from marketplace coverage, research shows. For example, 35 percent of uninsured adults didn't know about the ACA marketplaces in the fall of 2017 and an earlier survey found that nearly half of uninsured adults didn't know about marketplace financial assistance, even though many would likely qualify.
  • Second, CMS argues that the navigator program is inefficient, based on a misleading metric. The metric, which finds a relatively high program cost per person enrolled, focuses only on marketplace enrollments completed by navigators. It ignores navigators' other duties, including raising awareness about coverage more broadly. That often results in enrollment in the marketplace by consumers completing the process on their own or enrollment in other programs like Medicaid or the Children's Health Insurance Program (CHIP) that the CMS metric doesn't capture.

    CMS unfairly compared navigator performance to that of agents and brokers using this metric. The metric likely undercounts the enrollments completed by navigators because it links enrollments to navigators using identification numbers that, up to last year, most navigators believed were optional to provide and that they have received little or no training in using. By comparison, insurance agents and brokers have long routinely used identification numbers to ensure they are compensated for work they've completed to enroll consumers.

    In addition, navigators' enrollment counts may be lower than typical insurance brokers' because they work with hard-to-reach and vulnerable populations — including people who live in rural areas, have limited access to the Internet, have limited English proficiency, or have disabilities or other special needs — who often take more time to assist and may have complex eligibility or coverage questions.

  • Third, CMS suggests that agents and brokers reimbursed by health insurers can replace navigators. But navigators differ from agents and brokers in that they are required to provide fair and impartial information about health plan options, rather than promoting particular options. They also provide services that agents and brokers generally don't, such as making referrals for individuals to get appropriate assistance if they have a grievance related to their coverage, helping eligible individuals enroll in Medicaid or CHIP, and assisting people in resolving eligibility inconsistencies when their application does not match federal data records.   

Unfortunately, CMS also indicates that it seeks to interfere with navigators' impartial role by pushing them to promote limited-benefit coverage options, "such as association health plans, short-term, limited-duration insurance, and health reimbursement arrangements." As we've explained, such plans can leave consumers exposed to significant financial risk if they become ill or injured, and the proliferation of such plans will result in higher costs for people needing comprehensive coverage.

Finally, the funding announcement, building on an earlier CMS rule, opens the door to other significant changes that may leave consumers in some states without access to in-person, marketplace-funded assistance. The CMS rule changed the parameters for navigator program design, no longer requiring that they have a physical presence in the state they serve or that at least one navigator group in a state be a community-based non-profit focused on vulnerable populations.

Building on these changes, CMS encourages a single group to apply as the navigator organization serving multiple states. It claims that there's less need for face-to-face assistance, and it encourages navigator groups to present "less resource-intensive" outreach and enrollment strategies, like relying on virtual or mobile assistance to consumers. But some consumers — often including the vulnerable populations that navigators have designed their programs to serve — continue to need and seek in-person help.

The dramatic cut in navigator funding and other changes to the program will weaken navigators' effectiveness and ultimately reduce the viability of community-based enrollment and outreach programs tailored to each state's diverse populations. As a result, fewer people will get the impartial assistance they need to enroll in and maintain coverage.



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Chart of the Week: An Answer to the U.S. Wage Puzzle [feedly]

Chart of the Week: An Answer to the U.S. Wage Puzzle
https://blogs.imf.org/2018/07/10/chart-of-the-week-an-answer-to-the-u-s-wage-puzzle/

By Yasser Abdih

July 10, 2018

Hiring is strong, but workers still aren't seeing big raises (photo: Kutay Tanir/Getty Images by iStock).

Wages in the US have grown slowly in recent years, even as the unemployment rate has fallen to the lowest levels in decades. This is puzzling. Economic theory and common sense suggest that companies competing for a shrinking pool of available workers would have to raise wages as the labor market tightens.

What explains stagnant wage growth, then? The Chart of the Week, based on our new study, offers a plausible answer: slower growth in labor productivity—the amount of goods or services produced in an hour of work—and a decline in the share of income that goes to workers. Both have held wages down, overcoming the positive impact of a declining unemployment rate.

The chart shows that worker compensation (the red line) has increased just 2 percent or so each year, on average, since the Great Recession, down from 3½ percent in the eight years before. That's barely keeping up with expected inflation—the blue bars—even though unemployment, or "slack," has diminished, as indicated by the black bars.

How productive workers are is a key factor for employers when making compensation decisions.

A key explanation lies in slower labor productivity growth, as depicted by the orange bars. How productive workers are is a key factor for employers when making compensation decisions. If workers aren't producing as much, employers need to restrain pay growth to sustain profitability.

Another factor that has held down wage growth is a falling share of income that is paid to workers (the green bars). In an earlier study, we examined the reasons behind this decline and found that the bulk of the effect came from changes in technology that are linked to the automation of routine tasks, followed by import penetration. 

The role of slowing productivity growth underscores the importance of policies to encourage investment and innovation while facilitating the movement of capital and labor toward their most productive uses.

Policies also need to foster systems for continuous retooling and upgrading of worker skills. Although education and training programs would not immediately address the short-term adjustment costs for affected workers, over time they could enhance the resilience of employment and productivity of labor. Investing in education and training programs outside traditional channels could prepare future workers to keep up with technological progress and global competition.

Related links:
Understanding U.S. Wage Dynamics
What Explains the Decline of the U.S. Labor Share of Income? An Analysis of State and Industry Level Data 
Technology and the Future of Work



 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Krugman: Brexit Meets Gravity [feedly]

Brexit Meets Gravity

Paul Krugman

https://www.nytimes.com/2018/07/10/opinion/brexit-meets-gravity.html

These days I'm writing a lot about trade policy. I know there are more crucial topics, like Alan Dershowitz. Maybe a few other things? But getting and spending go on; and to be honest, in a way I'm doing trade issues as a form of therapy and/or escapism, focusing on stuff I know as a break from the grim political news.

Anyway, as Britain's self-inflicted Brexit crisis (self-inflicted with some help from Putin, it seems) comes to a head, it seems to me worth trying to explain some aspects of the economics involved that should be obvious – surely are obvious to many British economists – but aren't, apparently, as obvious either to Brexiteers or to the general public.

These aspects explain why Theresa May is trying to do a soft Brexit or even, as some say, BINO – Brexit In Name Only; and why the favored alternative of Brexiteers, trade agreements with the United States and perhaps others to replace the EU, won't fly.

Now, many of the arguments for Brexit were lies pure and simple. But their claims about trade, both before and after the vote, may arguably be seen as misunderstandings rather than sheer dishonesty.

ADVERTISEMENT

In the world according to Brexiteers, Britain needn't lose much by leaving the EU, because it can still negotiate a free trade agreement with the rest of Europe, or, at worst, face the low tariffs the EU imposes on other non-EU economies. Meanwhile, Britain can negotiate better trade deals elsewhere, especially the US, that will make up for any losses on the EU side.

What's wrong with this story? The first thing to understand is that the EU is not a free trade agreement like NAFTA; it's a customs union, which is substantially stronger and more favorable to trade.

What's the difference? In NAFTA, most Mexican products can enter the U.S. tariff-free. But Mexico and the U.S. don't charge the same tariffs on imports from third parties. This means that Mexican goods entering the U.S. still have to face a customs inspection, to make sure that they're actually Mexican, not, say, Chinese goods unloaded in Mexico and trucked across the border to bypass U.S. tariffs.

And actually it's worse than that, because what is a Mexican good, anyway? NAFTA has elaborate rules about how much Mexican content is required to qualify for zero tariffs, and this adds a lot of paperwork and frictions to intra-NAFTA trade.

By contrast, the EU sets common external tariffs, which means that once you're in, you're in: once goods are unloaded at Rotterdam they can be shipped on to France or Germany without further customs checks. So there's much less friction.

EDITORS' PICKS

Silicon Valley's Giants Take Their Talent Hunt to Cambridge

'Shaken' Rosenstein Felt Used by White House

What It Costs to Be Smuggled Across the U.S. Border

ADVERTISEMENT

And frictions, not tariffs, are what businesses are complaining about as Brexit draws near. For example, the British auto industry relies on "just-in-time" production, maintaining low inventories of parts, because it has been able to count on prompt arrival of parts from Europe. If Britain leaves the customs union, the risk of customs delays would make this infeasible, substantially raising costs.

These frictions are also why estimates of the cost of Brexit are comparable to estimates of the cost of a global tariff war, even though the predicted reduction in trade volumes is much smaller.

Still, even if leaving the customs union would be costly, couldn't Britain make up for that by getting a really good deal with Donald Trump's America? No.

Certainly the U.S. couldn't offer hugely valuable tariff reductions, for the simple reason that our tariffs on EU products – like EU tariffs on our products – are already quite low. You can find examples of high tariffs, like our 25 percent tariff on light trucks, but overall there just isn't much to give.

What about a Britain-U.S. customs union? That would be hugely problematic, among other things because given the asymmetry in size Britain would effectively be giving Washington complete control over its policy. Beyond that, no deal with the U.S. could be worth as much as Britain's customs union with its neighbors, because of gravity.

What? One of the best-established relationships in economics is the so-called gravity equation for trade between any two countries, which says that the amount of trade depends positively on the size of the two countries' economies but negatively on the distance between them. You can see this very clearly in British exports. Here's British exports to selected countries as a percentage of the importing country's GDP, plotted against the distance to that country:
Image



The point is that while America offers a market comparable in size to that of the EU, it's much further away, so that even if the UK could make an incredible deal with us, it wouldn't be worth nearly as much as the customs union they have.

All of this explains why May is trying to negotiate a deal that keeps the customs union intact. But that, of course, ain't much of an exit: Brussels will still set UK trade policy, except that Britain will no longer have a vote. So what was the point of Brexit in the first place?

Good question. Too bad more people didn't ask it before the referendum.

 -- via my feedly newsfeed