Wednesday, April 7, 2021

Calls to establish a regionally adjusted federal minimum wage are dangerously misguided [feedly]

Calls to establish a regionally adjusted federal minimum wage are dangerously misguided
https://www.epi.org/blog/calls-to-establish-a-regionally-adjusted-federal-minimum-wage-are-dangerously-misguided/

We need to raise the federal minimum wage. Its deterioration in value over the past five decades has exacerbated povertywidened inequality, and lowered wages for the bottom third of wage earners1—despite the fact that these workers typically are older and have more education than their counterparts a generation ago.

One misguided critique of the effort to raise the federal minimum to $15 in 2025 is that there is a need to establish a regionally adjusted federal minimum wage. In fact, federal minimum wage policy has always provided for tailored standards, by coupling a strong national wage floor with the ability for cities and states to adopt higher standards. Our ability to set a national wage floor is much easier now than it was decades ago when lawmakers last raised the federal minimum wage to new heights. In 1968, when the federal minimum wage was lifted to its highest value in U.S. history and coverage of the law was vastly expanded, there were much larger differences in wage levels throughout the country. Yet, we now have empirical evidence that establishing this unprecedented, nationwide minimum wage did not have adverse employment impacts.

Today, the wage levels of lower-wage states, primarily Southern ones, are much closer to overall national wage levels, so there is even less validity to claims that the federal minimum wage must be lowered to accommodate certain areas. Moreover, the 'bite' of a $15 minimum wage in 2025—i.e., the share of workers and businesses impacted, and the magnitude of resulting wage increases—will be well within the range of recent experiences of minimum wage increases in states and localities that studies have shown had little, if any, impact on employment. The proposed increase to $15 by 2025 will lead to improved annual earnings for nearly all low-wage workers.

$15 in 2025 is an appropriate level for the federal minimum wage

A $15 minimum wage in 2025 would be an appropriate and economically manageable level for the national wage floor. Data from EPI's Family Budget Calculator—which compiles the typical costs of basic necessities throughout the country—show that by 2022, there is not a county in the U.S. where an individual working full time, year round could achieve a secure standard of living earning less than $15 per hour.

Moreover, $15 in 2025 is the equivalent of $13.79 in today's dollars. Taking the federal minimum to this level would be an increase of about 30% above the 1968 peak, when the minimum wage was worth the equivalent of $10.59 in today's dollars. Over the past 50 years, productivity—the value of goods and services produced from each hour of work in the economy—has more than doubled. The minimum wage should be set at a level that ensures all workers, including those in the lowest-paid jobs, benefit from the economy's increased capacity to generate income—particularly when low-wage workers today tend to have higher levels of education than their counterparts in the 1960s.

Setting regional thresholds is bad policy and would cement racial and gender wage disparities

The argument that it would be better to adapt the federal minimum wage to local conditions is described as avoiding a 'one-size-fits-all' policy imposed on states regardless of local conditions. That is a mischaracterization of federal policy, however, since there is wide variation in minimum wages across states and localities (where states permit) as subnational governments adopt higher standards. The purpose of federal law is to set a national floor which provides a living wage to all workers and brings wages in lower-wage states closer to those in higher-wage areas.

It is critically important that the federal standard not be set to normalize or tolerate existing low-wage conditions in particular regions, industries, or occupations that are largely the result of historical racism and sexism. When the first federal minimum wage was being debated in the 1930s, Southern congressmen strongly opposed the federal standard, concerned that it would upset the white supremacist plantation system that dominated the South's economy. In fact, Southern lawmakers insisted that the federal wage standard should be adjusted by region to account for differences in costs of living. What ultimately led to the minimum wage law's passage as a single national wage floor was a "compromise" with Southern Democrats to exempt agriculture, restaurants, and a host of other service-sector industries that disproportionately employed Black workers. Even after it was amended in 1967 to cover more of these industries, the law still exempted most farmworkers—who today are majority Latinx—and allowed employers to pay a subminimum wage to tipped workers—who today are overwhelmingly women.

Adjusting the federal minimum wage based upon regional wage differences would serve to cement racial and gender wage disparities. Indeed, when we last analyzed a proposal to regionally adjust the federal minimum wage, we found that Black workers would be particularly harmed and women of color were a disproportionate share of those left behind, relative to a federal minimum wage without any regional adjustment.

Raising the minimum wage to its historical peak in 1968 had no adverse effects on employment

The 1966 amendments to the Fair Labor Standards Act expanded coverage of the federal minimum wage to over a fifth of the U.S. workforce that was previously exempt and raised the federal minimum wage to its highest level ever by 1968—the equivalent of $10.59 in today's dollars. In their groundbreaking 2020 study, Ellora Derenoncourt and Claire Montialoux find that the expansion of the minimum wage to previously exempt industries in 1967 raised wages of affected workers by an average of 34%, and dramatically reduced the Black-white earnings gap. They note, "the wage effect on treated [affected] workers is large because before 1967, many of them (predominantly Black workers) were employed at wages far below the federal minimum wage." Despite these large, government-mandated wage increases, the researchers found "a near-zero effect on employment."

Low-wage states have caught up since 1968

If the highest federal minimum wage in history—accompanied by the largest expansion of coverage since the law's enactment—had no measurable effect on employment, there is even less reason to think a strong national wage floor would yield negative effects today. As we explained in a 2015 paper, "The wage distributions across the U.S. states are closer together now than they were five decades ago. As a result, a federal minimum wage has a smaller 'bite' today in low-wage states than was the case in 1968. This should help to allay concerns that a higher federal minimum wage would hurt employment in low-wage states."

This can be seen in Table 1 from our earlier study. There has been a convergence of state median wages—primarily because state medians at the bottom have closed the gap with the national median. In 1968, there were 10 of the 30 state groups examined (the data grouped some states together) that had a median wage at least 10% below the national median and four state groups with a median more than 20% below the national median. By 2013, there was only one state group (Oklahoma and Arkansas) with a median wage more than 10% below the national median. This implies that any given minimum-wage level will have less of a differential impact now on low-wage states relative to high-wage states than would have been the case in 1968.

Table 1

In Table 2, we repeat this analysis from 1979 to 2018 using data on the median hourly wage of full-time, full-year workers in the Current Population Survey March Supplement, which allows us to identify each of the 50 states and the District of Columbia. The data affirm a similar convergence of wages across the country since the 1970s. In 1979, there were five states with a median hourly wage more than 20% below the national median and there were no such states in 2018. States are increasingly clustered within 10% of the national median. As mentioned earlier, this eases the challenge of adopting a strong national standard across the country.

Table 2

The suggestion for regional minimum wage thresholds is also sometimes offered as tailoring the threshold to local price levels. However, price differences across localities are reflected in the difference in their respective median wages and so are captured by the analyses in Tables 1 and 2.2

Some localities within states may have lower wages than the state as a whole, but analyses of local minimum wage impacts consistently show that higher minimum wages have not led to meaningful job losses, even at the local level. For example, Anna Godoey and Michael Reich examined the impact of higher minimum wages in low-wage counties, where the new minimum wage was as high as 82% of the area median wage. They found no evidence of negative employment effects. Similarly, Arindrajit Dube and Attila Lindner find that city-level minimum wages have raised wages of low-wage workers with "negligible" impact on employment.

What matters most is that higher minimum wages boost workers' annual earnings

Discussions around possible employment effects typically ignore the key metric for evaluating the utility of higher minimum wages: what happens to workers' annual earnings? As we explained in this 2018 paper, turnover in low-wage industries is high and low-wage workers frequently cycle in and out of jobs over the course of a year. If, in some areas, a higher minimum wage did negatively effect jobs, that doesn't mean low-wage workers would suddenly become jobless and never work again. The more likely scenario is that workers might see some reduction in their total work hours over the year—either from reduced schedules or more time in between jobs. But, because their hourly earnings are much higher, most affected workers earn as much or more than before over the course of the year, even if they are working less. Indeed, research on the minimum wage's effect on family incomes shows that higher minimum wages unambiguously raise low-wage workers' annual income, regardless of how their work hours may have changed.

Conclusion

The notion of adjusting federal wage standards based on local conditions sounds reasonable at first glance, but a more extensive examination suggests it is both unnecessary and could end up normalizing low wages in certain regions that reflect historic and current wage hierarchies established to hold Black workers' wages down. Federal minimum wage policy should continue to be set with a strong national floor supplemented by higher wage standards adopted by cities and states. Establishing a strong national floor is easier now than in past decades when Congress took the federal minimum wage to new peaks, because wage differences across states have declined substantially. Given the evidence that higher minimum wages do not have adverse employment impacts, especially when one looks at the annual earnings of low-wage workers, there is no reason why we should not enact a $15 national wage floor by 2025.

1. Authors' calculations using Economic Policy Institute Minimum Wage Simulation model.

2. For example, a simple correlation of state median wages with the Bureau of Economic Analysis's 2018 Regional Price Parity indices (which measure differences in state prices relative to the national average) returns a correlation coefficient of 78%. For all states, the ratio of the state median wage to the national median wage is within 1.1% of that state's regional price index.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Monday, April 5, 2021

Please join Zoom meeting in progress

Join Zoom Meeting
https://us02web.zoom.us/j/4869970437

Meeting ID: 486 997 0437
One tap mobile
+13017158592,,4869970437# US (Washington DC)
+13126266799,,4869970437# US (Chicago)

Dial by your location
        +1 301 715 8592 US (Washington DC)
        +1 312 626 6799 US (Chicago)
        +1 929 205 6099 US (New York)
        +1 253 215 8782 US (Tacoma)
        +1 346 248 7799 US (Houston)
        +1 669 900 6833 US (San Jose)
Meeting ID: 486 997 0437
Find your local number: https://us02web.zoom.us/u/kcrj6t4FI9

Join by Skype for Business
https://us02web.zoom.us/skype/4869970437



Sunday, April 4, 2021

Buy cheap and permanent Instagram Followers / Likes

Hi there

If you ever need more audience from your Instagram page, kindly consider
our Instagram services here
https://www.myinstabzz.co/


thanks and regards
Instabuzz Team







http://www.myinstabzz.co/unsubscribe/

Biden's infrastructure plan does not come close to tackling the vast extent of America's new housing crisis [feedly]

Biden's infrastructure plan does not come close to tackling the vast extent of America's new housing crisis
https://www.businessinsider.com/bidens-infrastructure-plan-not-enough-tackle-new-american-housing-crisis-2021-4?utm_source=feedly&utm_medium=webfeeds

Activists outside a homeless camp in Philadelphia on September 9, 2020.

Cory Clark/NurPhoto via Getty Images

  • The pandemic has exacerbated the existing housing crisis, and Biden's plan does not go far enough.
  • There is no safety net for housing, making any assistance during economic recessions difficult to deliver.
  • The crisis was built by poor government policy. The current administration must take steps to ensure housing as a basic human right.
  • Lindsay Owens is the interim Executive Director of the Groundwork Collaborative.
  • Sammi Aibinder is Special Assistant at the Groundwork Collaborative.
  • This is an opinion column. The thoughts expressed are those of the authors.
  • See more stories on Insider's business page.

The spending plans that the Biden administration released this week laid out substantial investments into our nation's housing system, including $213 billion for building and retrofitting affordable housing units, $40 billion for public housing capital repairs, and grant funding to address zoning laws rooted in racial and economic exclusion. These proposals are a welcome first step to ensuring safe, affordable, sustainable shelter - and Congress should move swiftly to enact them - but they do not come close to meeting the scale of the housing crisis that has been underway in the United States for decades.

The reality is that although the failures in our housing system were exacerbated by the pandemic - to the tune of 10 million people at risk of eviction and more than $57 billion owed in back rent - the pandemic didn't cause them. Rents have been soaring for decades, consuming an ever larger share of the incomes of the lowest-income Americans (and during the pandemic, the divergence in rent for low-income tenants versus higher-income tenants has worsened).

While renter incomes grew by 0.5% from 2001 to 2018, rents increased by 13%. Median asking rent has more than doubled over the last 20 years, and in 95% of counties, a full-time minimum-wage worker cannot afford to rent a one-bedroom apartment. Black and brown people are particularly vulnerable to the extreme instability renters face. With a housing market this fragile during boom times, Americans never stood a chance when a crisis inevitably hit.

No housing safety net

It doesn't have to be this way. The economic impact of recessions, such as job losses and income declines, are largely predictable, and policymakers have put in place a number of programs to offset them. When Americans lose their jobs, they can apply for unemployment insurance; when their income and assets drop below a certain threshold, they qualify for nutritional assistance.

But when it comes to housing, there's no comparable safety net. The federal government currently offers no guaranteed form of housing assistance, and there are no countercyclical housing programs that expand during downturns or are triggered by economic indicators. This makes it almost impossible to quickly and effectively deliver any assistance that Congress does allocate during a disaster like this one. Variations in application and eligibility requirements across states and cities have led to backlogs in distribution of federal aid money, all while thousands upon thousands of applicants have been denied assistance.

The fragility of our housing market is not an accident; policy choices have led to a two-tiered housing market in which relatively well-off, mostly white consumers can achieve the American dream of homeownership - with the help of considerable federal subsidies like the mortgage interest tax deduction - while renters, who are disproportionately Black, brown, and low-income, transfer an increasingly large share of their income to landlords in the private market. Ultimately, the scarcity of affordable and accessible housing in our economy is not reflective of national resources - it is reflective of a centuries-long political debate about who is deserving of public investment, and therefore economic dignity and security.

Consider the federal budget for housing programs geared toward those with the lowest incomes. Federal spending on housing assistance relative to gross domestic product has fallen by 30% since the mid-1990s. Funding for public housing in particular has suffered profound losses: in the last 20 years the annual federal budget has only met operations needs for public housing across the country three times. On top of that, funding for repairs has been cut in half - a trend that can't be divorced from the long-standing political tradition of pathologizing poor and low-income Black communities. This continued disinvestment has resulted in the share of households receiving housing assistance declining to just one in five today. As the rental affordability crisis has worsened, the federal response has shrunk.

Meanwhile, recent estimates have shown that more than two-thirds of the government's total spending on housing is allocated toward subsidizing homeowners through tax deductions. The vast majority of benefits from this "entitlement" go to the wealthiest of households, and most Black and brown families are excluded entirely. By structuring housing policy and housing markets so that Americans' homes are their most valuable asset and source of equity, this country has essentially transferred safety net functions to private homeowners (and enabled white families to maintain wealth by passing down the homes they own over generations).

Calling on the Biden administration

Our government can make different choices. Housing policies that rely on the private market to develop, administer, or maintain housing stock for those who are housing insecure have not come close to meeting the need for millions of people, because genuinely affordable housing is not profitable. If the Biden administration wants to truly "Build Back Better" and deliver on the promise of stable housing for all, it must commit to massive, sustained public investments, and a significant shift in our narrative around who is deserving of those investments.

There is no one silver-bullet solution: a number of approaches must be taken at the federal, state, and local levels (both regulatory and budgetary) to put us on the path toward an equitable and resilient housing system. Experts across the field, including grassroots leaders, researchers, and policymakers, have laid out extensive agendas for these actions. The Biden campaign previously committed to fully funding rental assistance for all who qualify - another important start, but one that does not adequately address permanent solutions to housing unaffordability.

In addition to advancing legislation that, at an absolute minimum, meets the Biden administration's priorities for housing, Congress must move to repeal the Faircloth Amendment, which has prohibited any increase to public housing stock since its passage over 20 years ago. Congress and the White House must also enact policies and fund programs that prioritize rehabilitation and preservation - not demolition - of homes in disinvested neighborhoods. Keeping new and revitalized homes affordable will also mean a strong commitment to rent control policies that place strict limits on rent increases, as well as exploration of alternative social and collective ownership models that empower tenants and grant them the dignity and security of stable housing.

The path forward isn't easy, but the lessons from history are clear. We are long past due for a major course correction in our federal housing policy: not just to patch things up in case of emergency, but to remedy longstanding inequities and recognize shelter as a basic right in the wealthiest country in the world.

Read the original article on Business Insider

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Friday, April 2, 2021

Enlighten Radio:Talkin Socialism: The Muddy Road

The Red Caboose has sent you a link to a blog:



Blog: Enlighten Radio
Post: Talkin Socialism: The Muddy Road
Link: https://www.enlightenradio.org/2021/04/talkin-socialism-muddy-road.html

--
Powered by Blogger
https://www.blogger.com/

The Spread in Labor Costs Across the European Union [feedly]

A fascinating dive from Tim Taylor on the spread of labor costs across the EU, and the institutional (including political) and economic reasons.

The Spread in Labor Costs Across the European Union
https://conversableeconomist.blogspot.com/2021/03/the-spread-in-labor-costs-across.html

In a common market, labor costs will look fairly similar across areas. Sure, there will be some places with differing skill levels, different mixes of industry, and different levels of urbanization, thus leading to somewhat higher or lower labor costs. But over time, workers from lower-pay areas will tend to relocate to higher-pay areas and employers in higher-pay areas will tend to relocate to lower-pay areas. Thus, it's interesting that the European Union continues to show large gaps in hourly labor costs. 

Here are some figures just released by Eurostat (March 31, 2021) on labor costs across countries. As you can see, hourly labor costs are up around €40/hour in Denmark, Luxembourg, and Belgium, but €10/hour or below in some countries of eastern Europe like Poland or the Baltic states like Lithuania. (For comparison, a euro is at present worth about $1.17 in US dollars. Norway and Iceland are not part of the European Union, but they are part of a broader grouping called the European Economic Area.)

Another major difference across EU countries is in what share of the labor costs paid by employers represent non-wage costs--that is, payments made by employers directly to the government for pensions and other social programs. In France and Sweden, these non-wage costs are about one-third of total hourly labor costs. It's interesting that in Denmark, commonly thought of as a Scandinavian high social-spending country, non-wage costs are only about 15% of total labor costs--because Denmark chooses not to finance its social spending by loading up the costs on employers to the same extent. 

These differences suggest some of the underlying stresses on the European Union. Given these wage gaps across countries, tensions in high-wage countries about migration from lower-wage countries and competition from firms in lower-wage countries will remain high. The large differences in non-wage costs as part of what employers pay for labor represents some of the dramatic differences across EU countries in levels of social benefits and how those benefits are financed. Proposals for European-wide spending and taxing programs, along with the desire of higher-income EU countries not to pay perpetual subsidies to lower-income countries, run into these realities every day. 

For comparison, here are some recent figures from the US Census Bureau on average employer costs per hour  across the 10 Census "divisions."  Yes, there are substantial differences between, say, the Pacific or New England divisions and the East South Central or West South Central divisions. But the United States is much more of a unified market than the European Union, both in wage levels and in the way non-wage labor costs are structured, and so the gaps are much smaller. 



 -- via my feedly newsfeed