Friday, September 21, 2018

Middle-Class Influence vs. Working-Class Character [feedly]

Middle-Class Influence vs. Working-Class Character
https://workingclassstudies.wordpress.com/2018/09/10/middle-class-influence-vs-working-class-character/

"Jesse" is one of a cohort of 80 students sociologist Jessica Calarco observed from the 3rdthrough the 5th grades and then revisited in middle school for her new book, Negotiating Opportunities: How the Middle Class Secures Advantages in School.  Calarco also interviewed the students' parents. Her research reveals that middle-class children practice "strategies of influence" in school because their parents prioritize academic success, while working-class kids generally follow "strategies of deference" because their parents care more about developing long-term character.

In middle school Jesse lost a homework packet and simply accepted a "0" grade when the assignment was due.  Several weeks later his mother found the packet and made Jesse complete it.  When Jesse turned it in, his teacher "firmly, and a bit incredulously" returned the packet ungraded, saying: "It's a little too late for that now.  I mean, that [assignment] was like a month ago."  Here's how Calarco describes Jesse's reaction:

"Jesse does not look up.  He nods slowly, but he keeps his shoulders hunched forward and his head low.  As Ms. Cartwright heads back to her desk, Jesse glances up at me, his face and shoulders heavy with resignation.  He murmurs quietly, almost sadly: 'It wasn't to get a better grade.  It was to make me a better person.'"

Jesse later explained to Calarco that his mother had told him to complete the late assignment not to improve his grade but because it was the right thing to do – "to work hard and take responsibility for his actions."

Jesse is from a working-class family, and Calarco recounts in heart-breaking detail how the working-class kids she observed are disadvantaged in grade school by their inability and unwillingness to push teachers to give them more time on a test, help them with answers, and allow them to turn in homework late. Middle-class kids, on the other hand, often treat teachers' instructions as but opening statements in a game of negotiating that these kids become amazingly good at as early as the 4th grade.

According to Calarco, middle-class kids are taught to question and negotiate with the authority of their teachers, who are there to serve and help them. They learn that children should ask for help and seek  special accommodations when they need them.  Working-class kids, conversely, are taught to defer to teachers, to do what they're told, and not to burden teachers with unnecessary questions but to work out their problems on their own.

Calarco argues that it is not only teachers' own middle-class predispositions that disadvantage working-class students (a "hidden curriculum" noted by other scholars like Annette Lareau), but middle-class kids' own crafty agency, and their knowledge that they can count on their parents to intervene if necessary, that makes it nearly impossible for teachers to give the same time and attention to working- as to middle-class kids.  In Calarco's observation, teachers are often frustrated with the demands middle-class kids make on them and appreciative of the working-class kids' deference and respect.  But the middle-class students are so confident, persistent, and often humorously, good-heartedly creative in seeking attention that as a practical matter, teachers have to give them more time just to get through their day.  This dynamic is further aided by working-class kids' commitment to not being a bother to teachers and to working out things on their own, and many of them see what the middle-class kids are doing as undignified begging at best or even cheating, which they disdain ever doing.   At a Working-Class Studies conference where she presented some of this research, I asked Calarco whether the working-class kids' disdain for middle-class negotiating might be based in a commitment to personal integrity.  She said, "Oh, for sure, though nobody used those words, of course."

As for remedies, Calarco argues against both teaching working-class kids to negotiate better or urging middle-class parents to restrain from teaching their children strategies of influence.  Rather, she advocates for teachers and schools to enforce sharper boundaries against negotiating the special deals middle-class kids are so good at bargaining for and to stick to those boundaries when parents complain and threaten to go to the school board.

I found her arguments for that approach sensible and cogent, but as with many remedies for addressing our growing inequalities, it puts too much responsibility on only one of our institutions and on teachers, whom Calarco so vividly shows want to treat all their students equally and often work ingeniously if unsuccessfully to do so.  I wish Calarco had pulled back a bit to a larger frame that built on one of her most insightful paragraphs:

"All the parents . . . regardless of class or mobility, wanted to support their children's academic success.  At the same time, parents worried that too much support could undermine their children's development of good character (i.e., respect, responsibility, and work ethic).  Middle-class and working-class parents alike struggled with how to balance those seemingly competing priorities.  Ultimately, middle-class parents prioritized good grades, and working-class parents prioritized good character.  Both groups, however, made those choices with reservations."

She doesn't spell out the reservations, maybe because they're pretty obvious.  As Jesse's story suggests, he just wanted to be "a better person," not to be too much of a bother, and for sure not a beggar or a cheater.  He could do with some negotiating skills, and with some more willingness to speak up for himself so he can be treated more fairly.  But no matter what he does, he'll never catch up to the increasingly manipulative influencing skills the middle-class kids are developing – partly, and importantly, because neither he nor his parents want him to.  By prioritizing good character, however, he is gradually undermining his academic competitiveness and eventually his competitiveness in a bifurcated labor market that increasingly has only low-wage and high-wage jobs that track education levels.  His parents may sense that, and thus their reservations.  Middle-class parents' reservations are likely based on the same perception – that if their kids have to sacrifice a little character and integrity to achieve academic success, it will be worth it in the long run because it will improve their chances of getting one of those increasingly rare jobs with good wages and conditions.  But is this really what middle-class parents want: Finagling, transactional grade-hounds constantly seeking competitive advantage so they can find a career, not just a job, a career that may value those same finagling, manipulative transactional skills they're honing in school?

I doubt that is what any parent wants, but those are the pressures being put on us by the increasing distance between good jobs and bad jobs based on educational attainment.  Parents should not have to prioritize between good grades and good character.  We need to attack our growing inequalities with higher wages and better conditions for all the bad jobs that do much of the work we all depend upon.  In the long run, even most winners can't really win in a winner-take-all society.

Negotiating Opportunities is full of carefully observed interactions among kids, parents, and teachers nearly all of whom are trying to do their best most of the time. But they're doing it within a socioeconomic structure where trying to build character and maintain personal integrity can increase your chances of having low wages and lousy working conditions, while in order to gain decent working and living environments and some discretionary income, you may have to trim your concern for character and integrity and to get really good at treating human relationships as simply transactional.

Jack Metzgar


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Intangibles, and wealth in human capital, moving East...

Making Tariffs Corrupt Again [feedly]

Making Tariffs Corrupt Again
https://www.nytimes.com/2018/09/20/opinion/tariffs-trump-corrupt.html

Trump has perverted the process and undermined U.S. credibility.

By Paul Krugman

Opinion Columnist

Sept. 20, 2018


President Trump has imposed tariffs, seemingly on whim, on about $300 billion worth of imports.CreditCreditDoug Mills/The New York Times

In normal times, Donald Trump's announcement of tariffs on $200 billion worth of Chinese goods, bringing us closer to an all-out trade war, would have dominated headlines for days. Things being as they are, it was a below-the-fold story, drowned out by all the other scandals underway.

Yet Trump's tariffs really are a big, bad deal. Their direct economic impact will be modest, although hardly trivial. But the numbers aren't the whole story. Trumpian trade policy has, almost casually, torn up rules America itself created more than 80 years ago — rules intended to ensure that tariffs reflected national priorities, not the power of special interests.

You could say that Trump is making tariffs corrupt again. And the damage will be lasting.

Until the 1930s, U.S. trade policy was both dirty and dysfunctional. It wasn't just that overall tariffs were high; who got how much tariff protection was determined through a free-for-all of horse-trading among special interests.

The costs of this free-for-all went beyond economics: They undermined U.S. influence and damaged the world as a whole. Most notably, in the years after World War I, America demanded that European nations repay their war debts, which meant that they had to earn dollars through exports — and at the same time America imposed high tariffs to block those necessary exports.



But the game changed in 1934, when F.D.R. introduced the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act. Henceforth, tariffs would be negotiated via deals with foreign governments, giving export industries a stake in open markets. And these deals would be subject to up-or-down votes, reducing the ability of interest groups to buy themselves special treatment.

This U.S. innovation became the template for a global trading system, culminating in the creation of the World Trade Organization. And tariff policy went from being famously dirty to remarkably clean.

Now, the creators of this trading system knew that it needed some flexibility to remain politically viable. So governments were given the right to impose tariffs under a limited set of circumstances: to give industries time to cope with import surges, to respond to unfair foreign practices, to protect national security. And in the U.S. the power to impose these special-case tariffs was vested in the executive branch, on the understanding that this power would be used sparingly and judiciously.

Then came Trump.

So far, Trump has imposed tariffs on about $300 billion worth of U.S. imports, with tariff rates set to rise as high as 25 percent. Although Trump and his officials keep claiming that this is a tax on foreigners, it's actually a tax hike on America. And since most of the tariffs are on raw materials and other inputs into business, the policy will probably have a chilling effect on investment and innovation.

But the pure economic impact is only part of the story. The other part is the perversion of the process. There are rules about when a president may impose tariffs; Trump has obeyed the letter of these rules, barely, but made a mockery of their spirit. Blocking imports from Canada in the name of national security? Really?


Even the big China announcement, supposedly a response to unfair Chinese trade practices, was basically a put-up job. China is often a bad actor in the international economy. But this kind of retaliatory tariff is supposed to be a response to specific policies, and offer the targeted government a clear way to satisfy U.S. demands. What Trump did was instead to lash out based mainly on a vague sense of grievance, with no end game in sight.

In other words, when it comes to tariffs, as with so many other things, Trump has basically abrogated the rule of law and replaced it with his personal whims. And this will have a couple of nasty consequences.

First, it opens the door for old-fashioned corruption. As I said, most of the tariffs are on inputs into business — and some businesses are getting special treatment. Thus, there are now substantial tariffs on imported steel, but some steel users — including the U.S. subsidiary of a sanctioned Russian company —were granted the right to import steel tariff-free. (The Russian subsidiary's exemption was reversed after it became public knowledge, with officials claiming that it was a "clerical error.")

So what are the criteria for these exemptions? Nobody knows, but there is every reason to believe that political favoritism is running wild.

Beyond that, America has thrown away its negotiating credibility. In the past, countries signing trade agreements with the United States believed that a deal was a deal. Now they know that whatever documents the U.S. may sign supposedly guaranteeing access to its market, the president will still feel free to block their exports, on specious grounds, whenever he feels like it.

In short, while the Trump tariffs may not be that big (yet), they have already turned us into an unreliable partner, a nation whose trade policy is driven by political cronyism, and which is all too likely to default on its promises whenever it's convenient. Somehow, I don't think that's making America great again.
 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Can Trade Agreements Be a Friend to Labor? [feedly]

This is an important discussion, and is an even broader arena than discussed here because there is an inescapable link between trade inequities with respect to labor and immigration. Dani hits one of the key points: Focus on the establishment of elementary labor rights, not "standards" that may be simply impossible to negotiate or obtain solidarity across borders and the uniqueness of each nations' history, laws and customs.  The standards issues -- e.g.minimum wage, property qualifications work classifications, etc -- can work against unity, and also against nations with large public stakes in inputs to enterprises.

Also important: the Golden Rule of International Relations: Do not demand your partner make concessions you yourself would not accept in a similar situation.

**************************************


Can Trade Agreements Be a Friend to Labor?
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/trade-agreement-labor-provisions-small-practical-effect-by-dani-rodrik-2018-09
Sep 14, 2018 DANI RODRIK

To date, labor clauses in trade agreements have remained a fig leaf, neither raising labor standards abroad nor protecting them at home. Real change would require a significantly different approach, including how trade agreements uphold and enforce workers' rights.

CAMBRIDGE – Labor advocates have long complained that international trade agreements are driven by corporate agendas and pay little attention to the interests of working people. The preamble of the World Trade Organization Agreement mentions the objective of "full employment," but otherwise labor standards remain outside the scope of the multilateral trade regime. The only exception is a clause, left over from the 1947 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (the precursor to the WTO), which permits governments to restrict imports that are produced with prison labor.



Regional trade agreements, by contrast, have long taken labor standards aboard. The linkage in these agreements between preferential market access and adherence to core labor rights has become increasingly explicit. In the original North American Free Trade Agreement, signed in 1992, labor standards were shunted to a side agreement. Since then, US trade agreements have typically included a labor chapter.1

According to its proponents, the Trans-Pacific Partnership would have required Vietnam, Malaysia, and Brunei to improve their labor practices significantly – and Vietnam to recognize independent trade unions. And US President Donald Trump's administration claims that its revamped agreement with Mexico contains the strongest labor provisions of any trade agreement.

Developing countries have generally resisted inclusion of labor standards in trade agreements for fear that advanced countries will abuse such provisions for protectionist purposes. This fear can be justified when the requirements go beyond core labor rights and make specific wage and other material demands. For example, the new US-Mexico agreement requires that 40-45% of a car be made by workers earning at least $16 per hour.

Auto companies can certainly afford to pay higher wages, and this provision on its own may not undermine employment prospects in Mexico. But it is not an altogether salutary precedent either, insofar as it sets an unrealistic wage floor – many multiples higher than the average for the Mexican manufacturing sector as a whole.

On the other hand, developing countries have little reason to reject labor standards that address bargaining asymmetries in the workplace and fundamental human rights. Core labor standards such as freedom of association, collective bargaining rights, and prohibition of compulsory labor are not costly to economic development; in fact, they are essential to it.



In practice, the problem with trade agreements' labor provisions is not that they are too restrictive for developing countries; it is that they may remain largely cosmetic, with little practical effect. A key concern is enforcement. For one thing, charges of labor-rights violations can be brought only by governments, not by trade unions or human rights organizations. By contrast, investment disputes can be launched by corporations themselves.

Critics rightly worry that governments that are not particularly friendly to labor causes will not be keen to follow through. To date, there has been only a single instance of labor rights being pursued under a trade agreement's dispute settlement procedures, and the outcome is hardly encouraging.

Following two years of complaints by US and Guatemalan trade unions, the US government formally launched a case against Guatemala in 2010. When a final decision was announced in 2017, nearly a decade after the initial grievances were aired, the arbitration panel decided against the US, but not because Guatemala lived up to its labor rights obligations under its own laws. The panel did find violations of Guatemalan labor laws. For example, court orders against employers who had dismissed workers for engaging in union activities were not enforced. But it ruled that such violations did not have an effect on Guatemala's competitive advantage and exports, and therefore were not covered by the trade agreement!

There are two reasons to care about labor standards. First, we may have a humanitarian desire to improve working conditions everywhere. In this case, we should have equal regard for workers in the domestic economy and those employed in export industries. Focusing on the latter may even backfire, by deepening dualistic labor-market structures.

In principle, we could expand enforceable labor clauses in trade agreements to cover working conditions in the entire economy. But it seems odd to have the linkage in the first place: why should labor rights be left to trade negotiators and the commercial interests sitting around the table, and remain hostage to negotiations couched in terms of market access?

If we are serious about improving working conditions everywhere, we should resort to experts on human rights, labor markets, and development, and raise the profile of the International Labor Organization instead. The objectives of both domestic labor unions and international human-rights advocates are served better through other means.

One argument for linkage with trade is that it gives countries a real incentive to reform labor-market practices. But foreign aid agencies have long experience with conditionality, and they know that it is effective only under special conditions. The desire for change must come from within the country and be demonstrated by prior actions. Achieving reform by threatening to suspend material benefits – aid or market access – is unlikely to work.

Alternatively, the concern about labor standards may be narrower: upholding working conditions at home and preventing a race to the bottom. In this case, we should seek domestic remedies, as with safeguards against import surges. What is required is a mechanism against "social dumping" that prevents poor labor practices in exporting countries from spilling over to the importing country.

Such a scheme, if poorly designed, might deliver excessive protectionism. Yet even the overtly protectionist anti-dumping measures allowed under existing trade rules have not been overly damaging to trade, while providing an escape valve for political pressure. A well-designed safeguard against social dumping should do no worse.

Labor rights are too important to leave to trade negotiators alone. To date, labor clauses in trade agreements have remained a fig leaf, neither raising labor standards abroad nor protecting them at home. Real change would require a significantly different approach. We can start by treating labor rights as being on a par with commercial interests, rather than being an adjunct to them.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Links (9/17/18) [feedly]

Links (9/17/18)
http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2018/09/links-91718.html


 -- via my feedly newsfeed

Hurricane Anniversary Highlights Puerto Rico’s Need for Adequate Medicaid Funding [feedly]

Hurricane Anniversary Highlights Puerto Rico's Need for Adequate Medicaid Funding
https://www.cbpp.org/blog/hurricane-anniversary-highlights-puerto-ricos-need-for-adequate-medicaid-funding

A year after Hurricane Maria took an extraordinary human and economic toll on Puerto Rico, the island faces immediate recovery tasks as well as longer-term challenges that predated the storm, including a decade-long recession and an overwhelming debt burden. Inadequate federal Medicaid funding — far less than what Puerto Rico would have received if it were a state — has contributed significantly to the island's financial problems.  

 -- via my feedly newsfeed

By the Numbers: Income and Poverty, 2017 [feedly]

By the Numbers: Income and Poverty, 2017
https://www.epi.org/blog/by-the-numbers-income-and-poverty-2017/

Jump to statistics on:

• Earnings
• Incomes
• Poverty
• Policy / SPM

This fact sheet provides key numbers from today's new Census reports, Income and Poverty in the United States: 2017 and The Supplemental Poverty Measure: 2017. Each section has headline statistics from the reports for 2017, as well as comparisons to the previous year, to 2007 (the final year of the economic expansion that preceded the Great Recession), and to 2000 (the historical high point for many of the statistics in these reports.) All dollar values are adjusted for inflation (2017 dollars).

Earnings

Median annual earnings for men working full time fell 1.1 percent, to $52,146, in 2017.Men's earnings are down 2.5 percent since 2007, and are still 1.9 percent lower than they were in 2000.

Median annual earnings for women working full time fell 1.1 percent, to $41,977, in 2017.Women's earnings are up 0.9 percent since 2007, and are 7.1 percent higher than they were in 2000.

Median annual earnings for men working full time in 2017: $52,146

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -1.1%
  • 2007–2017: -2.5%
  • 2000–2017: -1.9%

Median annual earnings for women working full time in 2017: $41,977

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -1.1%
  • 2007–2017: 0.9%
  • 2000–2017: 7.1%

Incomes

Median household income rose 1.8 percent, to $61,372, in 2017. Median household income is down 0.1 percent since 2007, and is 0.8 percent lower than it was in 2000.

Median non-elderly household income rose 2.5 percent, to $69,928, in 2017. Median non-elderly household income is up 0.8 percent since 2007, and is still 2.7 percent lower than it was in 2000.

Median household income in 2017: $61,372

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: 1.8%
  • 2007–2017: -0.1%
  • 2000–2017: -0.8%

Median non-elderly household income in 2017: $69,628

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: 2.5%
  • 2007–2017: 0.8%
  • 2000–2017: -2.7%

Median household income for white, non-Hispanic households rose 2.6 percent, to $68,145, in 2017. Median household income is up 1.5 percent since 2007, and is 1.4 percent higher than it was in 2000.

Median household income for African American households fell 0.2 percent, to $40,258, in 2017. Median household income is down 2.9 percent since 2007, and is still 7.9 percent lower than it was in 2000.

Median household income for Hispanic households rose 3.7 percent, to $50,486, in 2017.Median household income is up 6.7 percent since 2007, and is 3.4 percent higher than it was in 2000.

Median white, non-Hispanic household income in 2017: $68,145

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: 2.6%
  • 2007–2017: 1.5%
  • 2000–2017: 1.4%

Median African American household income in 2017: $40,258

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -0.2%
  • 2007–2017: -2.9%
  • 2000–2017: -7.9%

Median Hispanic household income in 2017: $50,486

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: 3.7%
  • 2007–2017: 6.7%
  • 2000–2017: 3.4%

Poverty

The poverty rate fell 0.4 percentage points, to 12.3 percent, in 2017. The poverty rate is 0.2 percentage points lower than in 2007. The poverty rate is 1.0 percentage points higher than it was in 2000.

The child poverty rate fell 0.5 percentage points, to 17.5 percent, in 2017. The child poverty rate was also 0.5 percentage points lower in 2017 than it was in 2007, although it is still 1.3 percentage points higher than it was in 2000.

Poverty rate in 2017: 12.3%

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -0.4 percentage points
  • 2007–2017: -0.2 percentage points
  • 2000–2017: 1.0 percentage points

Poverty rate for children in 2017: 17.5%

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -0.5 percentage points
  • 2007–2017: -0.5 percentage points
  • 2000–2017: 1.3 percentage points

The white, non-Hispanic poverty rate fell 0.1 percentage points, to 8.7 percent, in 2017.The white, non-Hispanic poverty rate is 0.5 percentage points higher than in 2007, and is 1.3 percentage points higher than it was in 2000.

The African American poverty rate fell 0.8 percentage points, to 21.2 percent, in 2017.The African American poverty rate is 3.3 percentage points lower than in 2007, and is now 1.3 percentage points lower than it was in 2000.

The Hispanic poverty rate fell 1.1 percentage points, to 18.3 percent, in 2017. The Hispanic poverty rate is 3.2 percentage points lower than in 2007, and is 3.2 percentage points lower than it was in 2000.

White, non-Hispanic poverty rate in 2017: 8.7%

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -0.1 percentage points
  • 2007–2017: 0.5 percentage points
  • 2000–2017: 1.3 percentage points

African American poverty rate in 2017: 21.2%

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -0.8 percentage points
  • 2007–2017: -3.3 percentage points
  • 2000–2017: -1.3 percentage points

Hispanic poverty rate in 2017: 18.3%

Change over time:

  • 2016–2017: -1.1 percentage points
  • 2007–2017: -3.2 percentage points
  • 2000–2017: -3.2 percentage points

Policy matters

The Supplemental Poverty Measure (SPM) is an alternative poverty measure published by the Census Bureau since 2010 that is more sophisticated than the official poverty measure referenced earlier in this fact sheet. The SPM takes into account an array of typical expenses—such as housing, food, clothing, health care, and more—as well as people's income from both market sources and government programs. Using the Supplemental Poverty Measure, we can evaluate how government assistance lifts people out of poverty.

SPM poverty rate in 2017: 13.9%

Impact of government assistance on poverty as measured by the SPM:

  • Social Security kept 27.0 million people out of poverty in 2017.
  • Refundable tax credits (such as the Earned Income Tax Credit) kept 8.3 million people out of poverty in 2017.
  • The Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP, also known as food stamps) kept 3.4 million people out of poverty in 2017.
  • Unemployment insurance kept 542,000 people out of poverty in 2017.

SNAP stands for Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program.


 -- via my feedly newsfeed